|
Dec 19, 2003
Special Year-End Issue
Note: This is our final issue of the Global Economic Forum for this year
and it will remain on the website through the holiday season. Regular
publication will resume on Monday, January 5, 2004. Happy Holidays!
Global
Global: Global Venting
Global: Multinationals May Be in For a ‘Remittable’ Year
Currencies: Updated 2004 Currency Forecasts
Currencies: JPY - Diminishing Returns on MoF Interventions
Americas
United States: Unwelcome Disinflation and the Fed
Brazil: Agora e Growth
Mexico: Looking Beyond the Link
Chile: Stronger Still in 2004
Argentina: The Growth Trap in 2004
Europe
Euroland: A Domestic Demand-Driven Recovery in 2004
Euroland: Toward a Stability Pact, Version II
Europe - All: Disunited We Stand
Europe - All: Merging Europe
Euroland: New EU Entrants — Making Their Presence Felt
United Kingdom: A Balancing Act
United Kingdom: Slower Consumer Spending, But Rate Hikes No Disaster
Germany: Beware Reform Fatigue
France: Push on Reforms and Privatisation
Italy: Job Miracle Should Continue into 2004
Spain: Living on Hot Building
Netherlands: Turning the Corner?
Belgium: Rejoining the Pack
Sweden: Introspection
Emerging Europe: A Positive Growth Scenario
South Africa: Stronger Growth, Rand Permitting
Japan: The Year of Truth
Japan: ZIRP-Phobia
Japan: Less Reliant on External Demand
China: Bubbly Again
Hong Kong: Balancing the Costs and Benefits of Greater China Integration
India: Ready for Takeoff?
Asia
Asia Pacific: Parties, Solutions, Second Track and Social Capitalism
Global: Global Venting
Stephen Roach (New York)
The world
economy, as I see it, remains very much in a state of fundamental
disequilibrium. A US-centric global growth dynamic has given rise to
extraordinary external imbalances around the world. America, the world’s unquestioned growth
engine, is facing unprecedented imbalances of its own; the national saving
rate, current account, Federal budget deficit, and private sector debt ratios
are all at historical extremes. And an increasingly powerful global labor
arbitrage continues to keep high-wage developed economies mired in jobless
recoveries. The result is a unique confluence of tensions that have left the
global economy in a state of heightened instability. The venting of those
tensions could well be the main event in world financial markets in 2004.
The case
for global rebalancing has been an overarching theme of our macro call over the
past year. The urgency of such a realignment in the
mix of world economic growth has never been more compelling. Over the 1995–2002
period, the United States accounted for 96% of the cumulative
increase in world GDP — basically three times its 32% share in the global
economy. This was, by far, the most lopsided strain of global economic growth
that has ever occurred in the modern-day post-World War II era. Two sets of
forces have been at work in creating this unsustainable condition — a US
economy that has been living beyond its means as those means are delineated by
domestic income generation, and a non-US world that is either unwilling or
unable to stimulate domestic demand. As a result, an unprecedented disparity
has opened up between those nations with current-account deficits (the United States) and those with surpluses (Asia and, to a lesser extent, Europe). Such an unbalanced global growth
paradigm is not sustainable, in my view. The debate is over the terms under
which the coming rebalancing occurs.
The macro
fix for a lopsided economy is very simple — it mainly entails a shift in
relative prices. For a US-centric global economy, that implies a realignment in
the dollar — the world’s most important relative price. In that vein, a weaker
dollar needs to be seen as the principal means by which the tensions of an
unbalanced global economy are vented. The broadest trade-weighted index of the
US dollar is currently down about 11% in real terms over the past 23 months.
History tells us that global rebalancing will undoubtedly require a good deal
more dollar depreciation — perhaps twice as much as that which has already
occurred. That poses the important question as to who bears the brunt of the
dollar’s adjustment. The Europeans and Japanese believe they have suffered
enough and are pointing the finger at others — mainly China — to pick up the slack. US
politicians are also sympathetic to this line of reasoning. Consequently, the
role that China plays in venting global imbalances
is also likely to be a key issue in the year ahead. For what it’s worth, I
think this debate overlooks a critical consideration: Europe and Japan are wealthy countries that have
dragged their feet endlessly on reforms, whereas China is still a very poor country that
has been aggressive in embracing reforms. Why should China be called on to compensate for
adjustments that Europe and Japan are unwilling to undertake?
America must also bear its fair share in
the coming global rebalancing. And the problem is that the US economy is not in the best shape to
cope with the requisite adjustments. That’s because it has a record low saving
rate, sharply elevated debt burdens, and massive trade and current-account
deficits. Nor is growth alone likely to be a panacea for America’s shaky fundamentals. In fact,
there are good reasons to worry that another surge of US economic growth could
well exacerbate many of these imbalances The pivotal tension point in this
regard is America’s anemic net national saving rate —
the combined saving of households, businesses, and the government sector
adjusted for depreciation. This key gauge measures the saving that is left over
to fund the net expansion of productive capacity — the sustenance of any
economy’s long-term growth potential. Unfortunately, in the case of the United States, there isn’t any — America’s net national saving rate fell to
a record low of 0.6% of GNP in the first three quarters of 2003. To the extent
that domestic income generation continues to lag — precisely the outcome in America’s lingering jobless recovery —
another burst of private consumption, such as that now under way in the second
half of 2004, can only push saving lower. That, in turn, puts greater pressure
on foreign saving to fill the void — giving rise to increased trade deficits
and private sector indebtedness.
Such an
outcome only heightens the tension already bearing down on the US economy. A lasting recovery cannot
be built on a foundation of ever-falling saving rates, ever-widening
current-account and trade deficits, and ever-rising debt burdens. These
tensions must also be vented if America’s nascent upturn is to make the
transition to sustainable expansion. The bond market, in my opinion, offers the
principal means by which this venting can occur. And the outlook for bonds is
not good. A confluence of three bearish forces are at work — the Fed’s eventual
exit strategy from a 1% federal funds rate, a weaker dollar, and America’s
fiscal train wreck. Ironically, under these circumstances, you don’t have to be
worried about inflation to be negative on bonds. At the same time, if financial
markets ever did get a whiff of inflation, a real rout in bonds might ensue.
Higher long-term real interest rates do not temper all the imbalances that are
on America’s plate. But they could help — possibly a lot.
The key impact would be a reduction in the growth of the credit-sensitive
segments of aggregate demand. That would enable a long overdue rebuilding of
domestic saving, which would then act to reduce America’s current-account and trade
deficits. A lower pace of consumption growth would also go hand in hand with a
reduced expansion of indebtedness. A tough bond market may be just the medicine
an unbalanced US economy needs.
The
global labor arbitrage is a third major source of tension bearing down on
today’s global economy. The accelerated pace of replacing high-wage jobs in the
developed world with low-wage workers in the developing world reflects the
interplay of three mega-forces — the first being the maturation of outsourcing
platforms in goods (i.e., China) and services (i.e., India) on a scale and with
scope never before seen. The second factor at work is the Internet — providing
ubiquitous real-time connectivity between offshore outsourcing platforms and
corporate headquarters. In goods production, the Internet forever changes the
efficiency of supply-chain management. But for services, the Internet is a
transforming event — effectively converting the once non-tradable sector into a
tradable global marketplace. With the click of a mouse, the knowledge content
of white-collar workers can now be delivered anywhere in the world on a
near-real time basis. The unrelenting push for cost control in a
no-pricing-leverage world is the third leg to the stool of the global labor
arbitrage. Such environmental imperatives only heighten the incentives for
IT-enabled “offshoring.”
While the
global labor arbitrage continues to push costs and pricing lower, it does have
its dark side. Significantly, it continues to put pressure on job creation and
income generation in the high-wage developed world. Largely as a result,
consumers in the high-wage developed world end up defending their lifestyles by
drawing increasingly on alternative sources of purchasing power, such as
asset-driven wealth effects, increased indebtedness, and tax cuts. In my view,
vigorous consumption cannot be sustained in the context of the profound income
leakage that stems from the global labor arbitrage. That underscores yet
another source of disequilibrium that must be vented. In this instance, the
venting appears to be exacerbating the pressures bearing down on an unbalanced
world. That’s because it has taken the form of heightened trade frictions and
growing protectionist risks — developments that only intensify pressures on the
dollar and the US bond market.
The means
by which this confluence of tensions gets vented will likely be key for global economy and world financial markets in 2004.
There are two conceivable paths to resolution, in my view — the benign soft
landing and the ever-treacherous hard landing. Macro is not good at making the
distinction between these two modes of adjustment. Instead, it basically
identifies the forces that have given rise to disequilibrium and then depicts
the possible adjustments that must take place to reestablish
a new equilibrium. As always, the outcome is more dependent on exogenous
shocks. In the current instance, the shocks that worry me the most would be
those that might shake foreign confidence in dollar-denominated assets;
intensified protectionist actions from Washington would be especially
disconcerting in that regard. Equally worrisome is the magnitude of the current
state of disequilibrium — and the distinct likelihood that these unprecedented
imbalances can only be vented by big movements in asset prices. My deepest fear
is that the longer the venting of these tensions is deferred, the larger the ultimate
adjustments and the greater the chances of a hard landing.
Important Disclosure Information at the end of this Forum
Global: Multinationals May Be in For a ‘Remittable’ Year
Rebecca McCaughrin (New York)
Early next year,
Congress will consider a piece of legislation that could have important
implications for recipient countries of US foreign direct investment (FDI). The legislation, known as the “Homeland
Investment Act” (H.R. 767) and the “Invest in the USA Act” (S. 596), is part of
the broader international tax bill, and
proposes to temporarily reduce the tax rate on US firms´ repatriated
earnings from 35% to 5.25%. If the legislation
is passed ― and the chances are quite good, according to our government
relations team ― the tax amnesty could affect those economies that are
disproportionately dependent on reinvested earnings as a source of
investment.
The proposed
legislation would offer a great boon for US MNCs. Currently, the income earned by foreign
subsidiaries of US corporations is subject to US tax only once it is repatriated, encouraging
many multinationals to store their profits overseas in order to defer paying US
taxes on their foreign-source income. As
a result, less than one-half of foreign earnings of US companies is returned to the US parent in any given year. In 2002, for instance, US parents repatriated
just 39% of the total $124 billion in profits from their foreign subsidiaries,
reinvesting the remainder. Over the years,
this has resulted in the build-up of some $350-400 billion of profits parked
overseas.
No one knows for
sure how large the potential windfall of repatriated profits would be if the
proposed bill is passed, since not all companies will necessarily take advantage
of the provision. For instance, for
companies with cash-strapped foreign affiliates or relatively more attractive
overseas opportunities, no excess dividends, or with credits left over from
prior years, the amendment might not be a sufficient incentive to
repatriate. In addition, while some
overseas profits are stored in passive investments, like government securities,
others may be tied up in equipment, property, or other less liquid investments
that are not easy to repatriate.
That said, there is clearly a host of companies that would profit
from the legislation. Indeed, a number
of multinationals with significant overseas exposure, including
Hewlett-Packard, Eli Lilly, Merck, Intel, Sun Microsystems, and Dell Computer,
have formed a coalition to lobby in favor of the repatriation provision. Congress's Joint Committee on Taxation
estimates that the proposal would encourage US companies to repatriate roughly
$135 billion in earnings; this is consistent with our own valuation team’s estimates. There’s a wide range of other estimates in
the market, some as high as $400 billion during the year in which the
legislation takes effect.
Outside of the
direct impact on individual multinationals, there could also be an indirect
balance of payments impact. The income
balance (one of the three components of the current account) would not be
significantly affected by a repatriation of overseas profits, since this
component only captures income earned during the current year, not the income that has accrued over the last several
years. Moreover, no distinction is made between earnings that are distributed to the
parent and those that are reinvested; both have already been accounted for in
the income balance. However, to the extent the HIA provision encourages
companies to repatriate more overseas profits and thus reinvest less in foreign
subsidiaries, it could reduce the level of US direct investment abroad. How so?
Reinvested earnings, which represent the value
of retained profits in foreign subsidiaries that are reinvested in the host
country, are one of the three components of FDI — the other two being intercompany loans and equity capital. They are distinct from the other two
components because they represent both affiliate income and capital flows. The contribution of reinvested earnings to
the overall level of US direct investment abroad is substantial, especially in the last two
years, with profitability still on
the mend, repayments of intra-firm loans to parent companies increasing, and equity
markets still fragile.
We had already
expected reinvested earnings to come under pressure in the near term, since
there has been a decline in the infusion of new equity capital in the last few
years and thus a smaller pool of capital to reinvest. With the added tax holiday, the pullback could be more pronounced. To what extent? Let’s
suppose that the US invests a total of $140 billion of FDI in overseas markets and
reinvested earnings represent 40% of that amount. That’s roughly on par with average levels in
the last five years. If we assume,
generously, that firms reinvest half of their earnings in order to avoid the
tax incurred from repatriation and half is invested to take advantage of actual
overseas opportunities; and if we also assume that nearly all of those firms that
have sheltered their overseas earnings will take advantage of the tax amnesty,
then repatriation could yield a 20-25% decline in US overseas investment (a bit
less if equity markets continue to recover and companies become more willing to
use equity capital as a means of financing).
The impact on recipient countries would
not be uniform. Although reinvested
earnings accounted for an average of 42% of total US direct investment outflows
on a global basis during the last five years, this figure masks significant
regional differences. For instance, during
the period 1998-2002 a number of European countries were disproportionately
dependent on reinvested earnings as a mode of investment — i.e., the Netherlands (76%), Ireland (69%), and Switzerland (51%). These economies are
also more dependent on the US as a share of their FDI inflows from the rest of
the world relative to other European economies where the ratio of reinvested
earnings to FDI is lower, thus posing the possibility of a double whammy. In Latin
America, 31% of total FDI from the US was in
the form of reinvested earnings during the same period. Within the region, though, Argentina
and Brazil were clear outliers, as foreign subsidiaries have posted losses in
these economies in the last few years, so reinvested earnings have actually
been negative. By contrast, in Mexico,
where US multinationals have rapidly expanded their presence in recent years,
the ratio is at the high end, at 40%. In
Canada, the ratio of reinvested earnings to total FDI was close to the
global average. In Asia, reinvested
earnings proved to be a key means of investment for Singapore (53%), Hong Kong
(52%), and Taiwan (35%), but less so for Japan (25%), Korea (18%), and China
(14%) during the same period. We are not suggesting that countries that are
more dependent on reinvested earnings as a mode of FDI will be
disproportionately affected. Reinvested earnings also reflect confidence in a
host country, and that may well outweigh other priorities, including a powerful
tax incentive. However,
those countries where the incentive to reinvest earnings is driven more by a
desire to defer tax payments rather than by profitability will more likely feel
the effects of a pullback in US investment.
Bottom line: If the HIA legislation passes
and has the intended effect of inducing US multinationals to repatriate a
larger share of their overseas profits, the level of US direct
investment abroad could decline, with those economies with a high ratio of
reinvested earnings to FDI at greatest risk.
Important Disclosure Information at the end of this Forum
Currencies: Updated 2004 Currency Forecasts
Stephen L. Jen (London) & Tim Stewart (New York))
We are updating our currency forecasts
for 2004. Our two-year-old call for a structural USD correction should
continue to play out for a third year. However, the overshoot in EUR/USD
and GBP/USD is likely to be somewhat greater than we had expected, while the
trajectories for USD/Asia, including USD/JPY, remain relatively unchanged from
the previous forecasts. Our end-2004 target for EUR/USD is now $1.23 (up
from $1.22), and our new target for USD/JPY is ¥102 (down from ¥105). The
more significant change is that we now expect EUR/USD to continue to overshoot
in Q1 up to $1.28, before declining gradually for the rest of the year.
With GBP and AUD also exhibiting this overshoot pattern, we anticipate the
average value of the Fed's major USD index to decline by 9.5% during 2004,
compared to the 4.1% we had expected previously.
Forecast Changes
New
|
Mar-04
|
Jun-04
|
Sep-04
|
Dec-04
|
Avg-03
|
Avg-04
|
EUR/USD
|
1.28
|
1.25
|
1.24
|
1.23
|
1.13
|
1.25
|
USD/JPY
|
105
|
106
|
103
|
102
|
115
|
105
|
EUR/JPY
|
134
|
133
|
128
|
125
|
130
|
131
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Old
|
Mar-04
|
Jun-04
|
Sep-04
|
Dec-04
|
Avg-03
|
Avg-04
|
EUR/USD
|
1.16
|
1.20
|
1.22
|
1.22
|
1.13
|
1.20
|
USD/JPY
|
107
|
105
|
105
|
105
|
116
|
106
|
EUR/JPY
|
124
|
126
|
128
|
128
|
130
|
126
|
Source: Morgan Stanley Research estimates
The basic framework behind our
previous forecasts
Underpinning our previous forecasts,
which were published in September, we had several key thoughts. First,
the USD would remain structurally mispriced, on an index basis, and further
correction of the USD index was inevitable. Second, the rally in the EUR
was excessive relative to the JPY: More generally, the Asian currencies needed
to 'catch up' to keep the USD correction more balanced. Third, emerging
market currencies, particularly Latin American currencies, were lagging badly
behind in the USD sell-off, and would likely catch-up with the majors.
Thus, we were looking for the USD to continue to correct, but for such a
correction to be more balanced between Europe and Asia and
between the major and minor currencies.
What has changed?
Three key developments since September
have altered our outlook for 2004.
Change 1 —
The de facto burial of the SGP and the strong EUR policy
The effective burial of the Stability and
Growth Pact (SGP) on November 25 was a watershed in this structural USD
correction, for it opened the way for EUR/USD to head higher. Having had
difficulties pushing headline inflation down below the 2.0% ceiling, the ECB
has consistently opted for a strong EUR policy. But the consequent
spill-over effect of such a policy was to push Euroland into a technical
recession in the first part of this year. Since November 25, EUR/USD can
head higher with impunity (since fiscal policy is now more able to compensate
for currency strength and a weakening in the economy brought about by currency
strength no longer endangers the pact).
Change 2 — Galvanised commitment in Asia to defend soft USD pegs
The G-7 Communiqué issued on September 20
in Dubai was effectively a
round of verbal intervention to talk USD/Asia lower. USD/JPY did decline,
but the rest of Asia barely
moved. We are now back in a bi-polar currency world, with Asia running soft pegs to the USD. In
contrast to Euroland, Asia is
very sensitive about the risk of a premature appreciation in their currencies
undermining their economic recovery. They are likely to maintain such
soft USD pegs until inflation becomes a problem. This means that Asia, led by Japan, will likely continue to resist the pressure for the USD to
correct.
Change 3 — The gradual recovery in
Euroland
The third event that changed our outlook
on the G-3 currencies is that Euroland has also begun to recover, mainly on the
back of the recovery seen in the US and Asia.
While the economic reasons for EUR/USD to rally sharply are not compelling to
us, a stronger Euroland economy, even if it is primarily supported by external
demand, should allow Euroland to absorb more EUR strength. EUR/USD may
rise by default, not by merit, and Euroland policy makers may have a misguided
strong EUR policy, but the bottom line here is that a stronger Euroland will
mean the economy can 'afford' to have a stronger EUR.
Our revised forecasts
Notwithstanding the developments
mentioned above, our basic story on the USD index remains unchanged. We
still believe that, compared to the fair value that is likely to prevail at
end-2004, the Fed's major USD index is around 5-10% overvalued. The
structural correction of the USD will, thus, be sustained well into 2004.
We continue to monitor all three aspects of the USD correction: magnitude,
symmetry, and speed.
Our year-end forecasts for both EUR/USD
and USD/JPY are not that different from the previous forecasts. However,
we are now looking for a further surge in EUR/USD in Q1. Because of this
prospective overshoot in EUR and GBP, the decline in the average rate for the
major USD index is now 9.5% in our revised forecasts, compared to 4.1%
previously. On symmetry, we now look for further upside in EUR/JPY in the
first part of 2004. USD/JPY will likely lag behind EUR/USD in the first
part of the year, but will likely continue its gradual decline throughout the
year. While downward pressures on USD/JPY likely will be great, we expect
the MoF to continue to conduct massive interventions to smooth out the
correction and support USD/JPY above ¥100. On speed, we continue to look
for an orderly adjustment in the USD index. While some bilateral exchange
rates (e.g., EUR/USD and AUD/USD) may overshoot, following Dornbusch's model of
overshooting, we do not expect the USD index to do so.
Coordinated intervention a risk in
2004
In a previous note we pointed out that the
four potential shocks in 2004 are (1) the US economy, in terms of both size and
quality of growth; (2) a slowing China; (3) protectionism; and (4)
geopolitics. With EUR/USD overshooting like this, we thus add to this
list the risk of coordinated intervention as the fifth potential shock that
matters for the currency markets. A USD correction concentrated against a
few currencies is neither healthy nor sustainable. It will, however, be
difficult for Euroland to reverse its policy on the EUR or exert pressure on Asia for greater burden sharing. The
alignment of interests between various currency blocs will be an important
issue in 2004.
Important Disclosure Information at the end of this Forum
Currencies: JPY - Diminishing Returns on MoF Interventions
Stephen L. Jen (London)
While
the market is fixated on EUR/USD at this moment, it is only a matter of time
before the spotlight turns on USD/JPY.
The MoF may continue to be successful with its
interventions in supporting USD/JPY at these levels for the time being. However, over time, massive interventions
could still fail if Japan’s recovery is
sustained. We lay out a portfolio-based argument:
1. Japan has a huge
amount of foreign assets.
As
a result of massive cumulative trade surpluses, Japan now holds a huge amount of
foreign assets. As of end-Q3 2003, Japan
as whole held US$3.5 trillion (¥378 trillion) worth of gross foreign assets
(GFA) and US$1.5 trillion (¥172 trillion) worth of net foreign assets (NFA).
2. This is not a preferred
portfolio mix, from Japan’s
perspective.
Japan has a strong ‘home
bias’ for investment, which suggests that the large GFA and NFA positions
in Japan may no longer be
preferred. In other words, if Japanese
investors had their way, they’d prefer to have lower levels of foreign
assets and more JPY assets, not from a carry perspective, but from the
perspective of the stock of their portfolios.
3. The idea of a
‘negative risk premium.’
The
concept of ‘negative risk premium’ is essentially the point that,
because of the aversion to further increases in Japan’s foreign asset
position, foreign interest rates will need to be considerably higher than those
in Japan to entice Japanese investors to send more of their capital overseas. Japan’s interest rates have
been persistently below those of most foreign countries. We believe that two main reasons for this are
(1) expected JPY appreciation (uncovered interest parity theory —
Japanese rates can be below foreign interest rates since after accounting for
currency appreciation, returns would be equalised)
and (2) the negative risk premium (Japanese rates can be below foreign rates
because Japanese investors would prefer not to further invest in foreign
assets).
4. The yield curve in Japan should rise and
steepen as the economy continues to recover.
I
have been arguing since early summer that Japan has seen its multi-year
economic bottom. As long as Japan continues to recover, there
should be pressures for the long bond yield in Japan to go up.
5. Massive MoF
interventions in USD/JPY are not consistent with the whole picture.
As
the MoF resists the USD correction through
intervention, it buys US Treasuries and helps keep interest rates in the US lower then they would
otherwise be. In addition, the more Japan recovers, the more Japanese
interest rates tend to drift higher.
But, as a result, the compressed yield differentials may end up being
too small to offset the combined effects of expected JPY appreciation and the negative
risk premium. Theory suggests that this
should lead to less private capital heading overseas. In turn, the Japanese long bond yield may
also be kept artificially low as private capital is trapped in Japan. In other words, the combination of (1) a
declining USD, (2) a recovering Japan, and (3) intervention that is
not consistent and not sustainable, continued official interventions would be
offset by a reduction in private capital outflows. This is one key structural reason why I
believe continued massive intervention will fail eventually.
Massive interventions are
likely in 2004.
The
structural USD correction is not yet complete.
What the currency world needs, however, is a better balance between EUR
and JPY and between the majors and the minors, during this structural USD
correction. If we assume that the JPY
rises by another 10%, on par with the expected movement in the major USD index,
USD/JPY would be below 100. (This is a conservative
assumption as I am not assuming any normalisation
between EUR and JPY.) The MoF will need to be prepared to intervene massively in 2004
to avoid 100 being broken. But the
amount of intervention necessary will have a meaningful effect on US interest
rates, just as Japan continues to recover. This will, as explained above, significantly
discourage private capital outflows and raise the risk that such interventions
may fail.
Bottom line.
The more the MoF intervenes, the more the Japanese private sector will
hold back on their foreign investment, making the interventions themselves an
exercise with diminishing returns. Heavy
intervention in 2004 will be necessary to hold USD/JPY above 100, but risks to
USD/JPY will still be biased to the downside of 100.
Important Disclosure Information at the end of this Forum
United States: Unwelcome Disinflation and the Fed
Richard Berner and David Greenlaw (New York)
November’s shocking dip in “core” inflation measured by
the Consumer Price Index (CPI) has reopened the twin debates about the
inflation outlook and what it means for the Fed. The November decline of
0.1% brought year-over-year core inflation to just 1.1% — the lowest reading
since May 1963. Moreover, the softness in pricing extended to both goods
and services, with core commodity prices falling by 0.4% and core services
flat. And given lingering biases in the CPI, core inflation could be below
the 1% to 2% range that represents the Fed’s presumed definition of price
stability. As a result, November’s reading seems to up the ante on the
risks of an “unwelcome decline in inflation.”
While we are mindful of the downside risks, we
disagree. Core retail inflation probably has bottomed, in our view, as
the case for a rebirth of pricing power is intact and signs of it are already
visible at earlier stages of the pipeline. It’s worth remembering that
core inflation last declined on a monthly basis in December 1982; and that over
the following year cyclical forces lifted core inflation to 3.9%. Of
course, that was then. The economy and the forces affecting inflation
have changed significantly over the past two decades, so over the course of
2004, only a slow rise is likely. This inflation environment will
reinforce the Fed’s determination to stay on hold in the face of strong
growth. While the Fed won’t likely tighten monetary policy soon, these
crosscurrents underscore the importance of straight talk from the Fed about its
longer-term game plan.
It’s a critical juncture for retail inflation. At
work are two sets of overlapping forces that have so far netted to
declines. The first set is disinflationary: It
includes significant slack in the U.S.
and global economies, three years of subpar economic
performance, and growing supply from new outsourcing platforms in Asia.
One measure of that slack, the so-called “output gap” (the difference between
actual and “potential” GDP) currently stands at about 2% of GDP, a spread that
in the past has been associated with declining inflation. And despite the
21% decline in the dollar’s value on a trade-weighted basis against major
currencies, prices of imported consumer goods have until very recently
declined. No doubt, the fixity or slow appreciation of several Asian
currencies against the dollar and the desire of other exporters to keep US
market share has suppressed that “pass through.”
There’s no mistaking the fact that inflation is at
historical lows by any measure. However, just as the CPI may have
overstated the slight rise in core inflation in 2000-01 by a factor of two, it
likely has overstated core disinflation in the past two years.
Core CPI inflation rose by nearly a percentage point in the earlier period, while
it declined by about 160 basis points over the past two years. In
contrast, the core personal consumption price index, which is the Fed’s
preferred inflation gauge, showed an acceleration of half a percentage point in
2000-01, and a deceleration of 90-100 bp — as best we
can judge given incomplete official revised data — over the past two
years. Equally important, just as the core CPI overstated the rate of
inflation in the earlier period, it may slightly
understate it currently. Three
factors are especially important in accounting for the divergence between the
two indexes: a difference in coverage, the use of alternative price gauges for
some spending categories, and the methodology used to calculate each
index. For instance, shelter accounts for 31.7% of the CPI, but little
more than 15% of the PCE price index (for details, see “Will the Real Core
Inflation Measure Please Stand Up?” Global Economic Forum, July
16, 2001).
Looking ahead, we expect that cyclical reflationary
forces will begin to gain the upper hand and gradually lift inflation, however
it is measured. Corporate America has reduced capacity; for example,
manufacturing capacity apart from motor vehicles and information technology
contracted by half a percent over the past two years. That helps explain
why operating rates have jumped by 160 basis points in the past six months on
the back of moderate production gains. Monetary policy is clearly reflationary, evidenced partly by the dollar’s ongoing,
orderly decline. The effects are beginning to show up clearly: For example, non-energy import
prices rose by 1% in the year ended in November, the
fastest pace in five years. Finally, above-trend growth is
beginning to close the output gap. Even if potential growth is 4%, if our
growth prognosis is close to the mark, the gap will have closed by more than a
full percentage point by mid-2004. And we believe that both the change in
the gap as well as its width bear on future inflation.
But uncertainty clouds our appraisal. We’ve already noted
that, despite improvements, statisticians still measure inflation imperfectly,
so we’re not quite sure where we are starting from. For example, the
Schultze report argues cogently that the CPI may understate some important
price measures (see At What Price? Conceptualizing and Measuring
Cost-of-Living and Price Indexes, ed. Charles Schultze and Christopher
Mackie [Washington, DC:
National Academy
Press, 2001]). Second, we’re still guessing at potential growth past and
future, so the size of the output gap and how fast it will close are
unknown. For example, if potential growth was half a percentage point
higher than previously thought over the past four years, the gap would be 4% of
GDP, not 2%. Indeed Fed staff research suggests that errors in measuring
the output gap have at times been larger than the gap itself.
While the Fed won’t likely tighten monetary policy soon,
in this uncertain environment the Fed owes market participants and the public
at large an explanation of its future game plan. Three issues are
important: Where policy is, where it will ultimately go, and how fast it must
get there. In our view, monetary policy is extremely — and appropriately
— accommodative, with the current real Federal funds rate essentially zero.
However, monetary policy is a long way from a “neutral” setting; in a
high-productivity growth economy, the “natural” or real long-term Federal funds
rate is probably about 3%. In our view, policy should be back to neutral
when the output gap has vanished, as the Taylor Rule suggests. But
there’s no chance that the Fed will feel compelled to return policy to neutral
in a hurry. With ultra-low inflation and only a gradual rise likely, a
return to policy neutrality could take two years or more.
Fed officials have recently made progress in communicating
that strategy through speeches and statements. Indeed, the line of
reasoning just outlined is consistent with the FOMC 's reference to the fact
that "economic performance in line with their expectations would not entirely
eliminate currently large margins of unemployed labor and other resources until
perhaps the latter part of 2005 or even later" (see the October 28 FOMC
minutes). But that statement, especially on the heels of the FOMC’s shift in its inflation risk assessment, did create
confusion. Some read this passage as an indication that the Fed planned
to avoid hiking rates until 2005 or beyond. In fact, it actually seems to
be nothing more than a reasonable assessment of the point at which the monetary
authority will need to have a neutral (or close to neutral) policy stance in
place.
From our standpoint, while Greenspan & Co have
certainly sent some confusing signals in recent weeks, a careful reading of the
FOMC statement and the October minutes does send a clear message. The
FOMC linked the “considerable period” to circumstances, not just the
calendar. The minutes clearly note the differences between today’s
too-low inflation environment and those of the past, with straightforward
implications for policy. Yet financial market participants also
compounded the problem by misinterpreting a relatively innocuous reference to
the output gap.
Fed officials have convened yet another committee to offer
suggestions on how to improve communication of policy strategy and
intent. From that process, more changes are likely, and, we are certain,
straighter talk. We hope the committee will adopt some suggestions we’ve
offered before: Keep it simple. Be clear about goals. State what you just did and why.
Clearly state the main medium-term risks to the outlook. State your
policy bias: Are you north or south of equilibrium? Finally, speed up the
release of the minutes, to the end of the second week after the meeting (see
“Transparency, Targets and Rules in Monetary Policy,” Global Economic Forum,
September 5, 2003). We think a growing number of Fed officials agree
that early release of the FOMC minutes would be helpful. In a November interview,
Fed Governor Bernanke stated: "I would be in
favor of moving up the release date of the minutes from the FOMC meetings and
thus getting out more timely information about the Fed's deliberations. That
would provide much more forward-looking information and reduce the burden on
the statement that follows the meetings."
Important Disclosure Information at the end of this Forum
Brazil: Agora e Growth
Gray Newman and Claudia Castro (New York)
After the dramatic improvement in Brazilian asset
prices during 2003, it may seem hard to imagine that there is still more good
news to come from Brazil. But
we believe that there is: We expect 2004 to be the year of a full-fledged
recovery, producing the best growth — real GDP up at least 4.4% — in five
years. Indeed, the good news is that the recovery in Brazil has already begun.
The first signs of the recovery have come from durable goods consumption,
brought about by the combination of enormous pent-up demand and an improvement
in consumer confidence as the authorities have begun slashing interest rates.
The pent-up demand is hardly surprising. After all, during the past five years,
with the exception of 2000, Brazilians have suffered from a weakened economy.
The improvement in confidence is also hardly surprising. After a dramatic
contraction in private consumption at midyear — consumption saw its sharpest
quarterly drop during the second quarter of the year in more than a decade —
the central bank has cut interest rates by 1,000 basis points and is likely to
continue well into the first half of 2004, as we expect the Selic target interest
rate to fall to 14%.
Brazil enters 2004 not only with an unusually effective combination of
macro policies, but also with a positive progress report card on structural
reforms. On the macro front, the authorities have been able to use tight
monetary policy to control inflation while maintaining a strict commitment to
fiscal responsibility. The payoff is now coming, and we expect it to be
abundant during 2004 as the easing cycle supports an incipient consumption-led
recovery. Unlike the aborted recovery in 2001, this time Brazil
finds itself with a much more solid external position. Indeed, Brazil
will end this year with a record trade surplus near $24 billion, sufficiently
large to allow for growth without a significant deterioration taking place.
Finally, on the reform front, in an unprecedented move, controversial social
security and tax reforms have passed Congress simultaneously.
Notwithstanding progress on growth and reforms, Brazil
still needs to address enduring questions over its medium-term outlook. The
challenge for Brazil is how to deal with improved fiscal revenues that are likely to
accompany the return to growth. While the administration has underscored its
fiscal austerity credentials with a larger primary surplus than was ever achieved
during the past administration, good growth and improved investor sentiment can
be seductive. The magnitude of Brazil’s
debt is such that debt reduction must remain the principal priority of the
fiscal authorities. Of course, policies designed to produce growth are crucial
in order to have the resources to tackle the debt burden, and indeed one should
lead to the other, but that vulnerability can easily be overlooked in the midst
of a growth rebound.
Part of our cautionary note on Brazil in 2004 stems from the track record of Mexico in dealing with its abundance. The oil windfalls of 2000 and 2003 have largely gone to fund
current expenditures rather than being used to fund a well-designed oil
stabilization fund. Mexico’s strength has been in dealing with adversity: It has shown the
prudence to tighten its belt and endure the fiscal pain. Brazil’s
recent experience suggests that it has learned the same lesson. However, the jury
in both countries remains out on whether they will respond to the good times.
The abundance of growth in Brazil is
likely to be cheered by investors in 2004; how Brazilian policy makers deal with it, however, will determine whether the
cheer remains in 2005.
Important Disclosure Information at the end of this Forum
Mexico: Looking Beyond the Link
Gray Newman (New York)
After running on one cylinder for most of the past
three years (with modest consumer demand hampered by the lack of job growth),
we are beginning to see solid evidence of a recovery in Mexico’s real
economy. We expect the evidence we are now seeing to allow the debate over
whether the “link is alive” between the US and
the Mexican economies to be put to rest. However, we are unprepared to forecast
a return to the robust growth last seen in 2000 because of our residual
concerns over the quality and sustainability of the US
recovery. The problem of whether the link is alive had reared its head during
the second half of 2003, when the headline reports from the US showed an
economy on fire while Mexico’s GDP showed little or even negative growth during
the third quarter. The problem, of course, is that the US
manufacturing sector — precisely where the link between the US and Mexico is
strongest — had lagged the broader US
recovery. That, plus differences in how the growth rates in the two economies
are reported and the bias of much of the first signs of the turnaround in US
manufacturing toward high-tech (where links with Mexico are weaker) raised the
inevitable question whether China had so damaged the link between the two
countries that a US recovery could leave Mexico without growth.
At the end of 2003, however, the first signs —
initially on the trade front and now in industrial production — were visible
that the US recovery is indeed spilling over into Mexico’s
manufacturing sector. In fact, October’s industrial production report—once
properly adjusted for seasonality — marks an extremely positive break with the
weakness of recent months. Further, October’s trade report,
as well as the September report in our analysis, provide strong support
that the improvement in US demand seen in the third quarter has begun to spill
over into the Mexican economy. And with Mexican consumers in better shape after
the recent downturn than coming out of any past downturn — thanks to low
inflation, they have not seen their purchasing power destroyed — consumption is
set to benefit further.
The problem in Mexico
remains that the policy-making class appears unwilling to move forward on a
host of reforms that are crucial for Mexico to
boost its competitiveness. Investors initially thought the “convergence” thesis
held great promise for Mexico. Unfortunately, convergence has become a safety net. Thanks to the
forces of integration with the US
economy, Mexico continues to enjoy a steady flow of foreign investment. The
stability of those flows, accentuated by strong oil prices, tourism revenues,
and ever-growing remittances from Mexicans working abroad, have a pernicious
side: They have reduced to urgency
facing Mexican policymakers to tackle the competitive impediments facing Mexico.
The good news in Mexico is
that by the fourth quarter of 2003, the Mexican economy had begun to respond to
the US recovery. Consumers, who so far have kept the economy afloat thanks to credit and modest real wage gains, are now
likely to find improvement on the jobs front as well. The cyclical upturn is
likely to cause some of the concerns over the threat that China
represents to Mexico to recede. That in many ways is a shame. The greatest threat to Mexico,
in our view, remains the failure of policy makers and politicians to leverage Mexico’s
integration story. In the difficult months of 2003, when many Mexico
watchers were concerned that China’s
competitive challenge might have severed the link between the US and Mexico,
the policy making class in Mexico
failed to make progress on the reform front. If strong capital inflows robbed Mexico’s
politicians of any urgency to act then, what can we expect now that a cyclical
recovery is under way? Not much, I’m afraid. It is hard to be too upbeat on Mexico’s
medium-term macro prospects, even if I am wrong for being too cautious
regarding the sustainability and quality of the US
recovery. Yes, it is true that a turnaround in Mexico is
in the works. Much of the growth in 2004 will depend on how strong the US
recovery is. But the longer-term challenges for Mexico —
challenges highlighted by China’s
and India’s ascension — are not being addressed. That should give pause, even
as the cyclical upturn begins to gain ground and gives investor reason for good
cheer.
Important Disclosure Information at the end of this Forum
Chile: Stronger Still in 2004
Gray Newman and Claudia Castro (New York)
We expect Chile’s
economy to continue to gain ground in 2004 with growth near 4.5% — its
strongest performance since 1997. With real wage growth fairly constant, near
2% per year, Chile’s consumer has benefited from the improvement on the jobs front as
well as from greater access to credit. Unemployment is now at its lowest level
in five years. Meanwhile, we expect another strong year on the credit front as
banks are preparing for an aggressive increase in consumer lending, which has
been growing in the double digits during 2003. The prospects for copper prices
are also set to benefit Chile in 2004. Our metals team now expects copper prices to average $0.95
per pound in 2004, an 18.8% jump from the $0.80 forecast for 2003. And there
are signs that there could be upward pressure to the copper forecasts: By
mid-December copper prices had broken above $1.00. Unlike Mexico,
which appears to be on the wrong side of the ongoing debate over the importance
of China, Chile has benefited from stronger Chinese demand for its commodity
exports from copper to pulp and forestry products.
In addition, the prospect of a boost in activity from
the free trade agreement with the United States set to go into effect on January 1, 2004,
along with the outlook for another strong year of growth in Argentina
and a robust recovery in Brazil,
should also benefit Chile. While the direct impact from the reduction in trade tariffs from a
free trade agreement with the US is likely to be limited — we have seen
estimates that it can add anywhere from 0.2% to 1.2% of GDP — secondary
benefits from greater market access and increased investment flows are likely
to enhance the impact further. But of greatest benefit to Chile in
2004 is likely to be the improvement in the economic conditions of its
neighbors. While imports of consumer goods from Argentina
and Brazil have risen by nearly one-third in the first half of the year, the
benefits from a recovery in both countries are likely to more than offset the
additional competition facing Chile’s
manufacturing base.
While the rebound in Chile’s
real economy for the most part has been anticipated by Chile
watchers, the big surprise has been how much ground the currency has gained.
Part of the recent rebound in the Chilean peso — from near 700 in late August
to 598 by mid-December — appears to be the flip side of the excessive weakening
seen during the latter half of 2002 and the first months of 2003, when the exchange
rate broke above 750. But if there is a surprise in store for Chile
watchers in 2004, we think it is that the Chilean peso is likely to remain
strong. After all, the currency has suffered six years of decline. Today, the
economy is showing virtually no current-account deficit, unlike its position
during 1998 when the deficit exceeded 6% of GDP. With sound fiscal, monetary,
and debt fundamentals and its commodity-linked export base, Chile
appears to be ideally positioned to benefit from US dollar weakness and the
rebalancing of global demand.
The weakest link is the lack of progress in boosting
total factor productivity, which raises some concerns about the magnitude of
the peso’s upside. Indeed, were it not for our concerns over the progress of
global rebalancing, we would be even more optimistic on Chile for
2004. We are not in the camp that expects a global derailment, but we are not
ready to embrace an uneventful, smooth recovery in global trade. Unlike Brazil
and Argentina, which we expect to post strong growth in 2004 as part of a
rebound, our forecast of 4.5% growth for Chilean GDP in 2004 is all the more
impressive because it is coming off a good year in 2003.
Important Disclosure Information at the end of this Forum
Argentina: The Growth Trap in 2004
Gray Newman and Luis Arcentales (New York)
It should come as little surprise that Argentina
is leading the way in the rebound in activity in Latin America. After all, the
robust growth of 2003 comes after having suffered a dramatic collapse of nearly
20 percentage points of real GDP between late 1998 and 2002. But perhaps more
surprising is that Argentina is likely to have a repeat of strong growth in 2004, despite the
lack of resolution of a host of issues stemming from Argentina’s
default and devaluation two years ago. Indeed, we expect real GDP to grow by
6.0% in 2004.
The magnitude of the rebound is largely a function of Argentina’s
large output gap, which combined with a competitive currency, low interest
rates, and greater room for fiscal stimulus is likely to produce the second
consecutive year of the strongest growth since the beginning of the era of
convertibility in 1991. Thanks to the large output gap, Argentina
should be able once again to post dramatic growth in 2004 without a significant
pickup in investment spending. There is little agreement on the size of the
output gap in Argentina. We have seen a wide range of estimates for 2004, from 6% (assuming
growth near 7% in 2003) to 14% and some as high as 20%. Even at the low end of
the range, however, our 6% growth estimate for GDP in 2004 appears plausible
with only limited investment.
During the past year, the motor of growth in Argentina’s
economy has rapidly changed from net exports to investment (largely residential
construction) and now has moved to private consumption. The move to stronger
consumer-led growth should ease some of the concerns that the output gap is
quickly evaporating. Relative to net external demand, domestic demand is satisfied
with a greater amount of services versus goods. While both industrial output
and the services sectors fell by roughly 10% in 2002, industrial output has
soared, up 17.3 % in the first half of 2003, while services has so far lagged,
up only 2.2%. The lag on the services front suggests that there is significant
room for growth in Argentina before capacity constraints become an issue.
The turnaround is also be supported by a very
competitive currency. With inflation having rapidly come down from 41% in December
2002 to under 4% now, while the currency has depreciated by 65% since the break
with convertibility, Argentina’s
currency remains substantially undervalued. Again, we have seen a range of
measures of just how undervalued the Argentina peso is; what seems clear,
however, is that the currency is likely to continue to provide a substantial
boost to import-substitution industries and to aid net exports.
While it is hard to be critical of the much-needed
rebound in the real economy, we would highlight three risks that today’s
temporary boost to activity poses for long-term growth prospects. First, with a
repeat of strong growth in 2004, there is the risk that the political will to
move forward on the debt restructuring process may be reduced. While it is
difficult to imagine that policy makers or politicians can mistake the
bounce-back in 2003 as the beginning of a sustainable growth path, we fear that
another year of good growth may reduce the incentives to tackle the difficult
challenges surrounding debt restructuring. That, in turn, can be expected to
delay the recapitalization of the banks. With an economy growing without any
significant financial intermediation from abroad or from local banks, it may be
easier for politicians to postpone the issue of how to finance long-term
growth. Second, good growth may create an additional stumbling block to
progress on the debt front as bondholders demand higher recovery values for the
defaulted debt. The longer and stronger the recovery in the Argentine economy, the
greater the demands of bondholders are likely to be. Finally, good growth
(helped along by new distortional tax measures and a reduced interest burden)
may delay the day that policy makers tackle Argentina’s
fiscal challenge, which requires a rethinking of the revenue sharing
arrangement with the provinces.
At the core of Argentina’s
fiscal challenge of living within its own means is to revamp the relationship
between the provinces, which dominate government spending, and the federal
government, which dominates the tax base. This imbalance provides provincial
governments with few incentives to moderate spending, while attempts by the
federal government to increase taxes often create a new entitlement to the
provinces. Unfortunately, policy makers may feel less urgency to tackle the
politically charged issue with the provinces given the jump in revenues tied to
growth and new distortional taxes.
Argentina is unlikely to relinquish its status as the fastest growing major
economy in Latin America in 2004. Ultimately, however, we believe that Argentina
needs to address the residual damage of the meltdown two years ago, starting
with debt restructuring, a new agreement with the utilities, and a plan to
recapitalize the banking system. It also needs to deal with one of the sources
of the meltdown — the asymmetric relationship between the provinces and the
national government, which prompted it to live beyond its means. Otherwise, the
rebound that we expect to continue in 2004 is likely to turn into a growth trap
and leave Argentina ill-prepared for the future.
Important Disclosure Information at the end of this Forum
Euroland: A Domestic Demand-Driven Recovery in 2004
Eric Chaney and Joachim Fels (London)
The euro area is entering 2004 at a fast speed
Our business-cycle indicators recently converged to
acknowledge that the euro economy is eventually picking up steam. On our
estimates, GDP growth accelerated from 1.5% (quarterly annualized) in the third
quarter to 3.0%, at least, in the fourth one. This bodes well for growth and
corporate profits. Indeed, we expect GDP to grow 2.2% in 2004 (on a
non-calendar-adjusted basis), the fastest speed since the bubble year 2000. Even though the recovery was kick-started by a spectacular
acceleration in global trade growth in late 2003, that was then, and looking
forward we think that domestic demand will be the main driver of growth in 2004.
We count on consumers to fuel domestic demand
After the burst of the technology bubble, which had
fuelled both consumers’ appetite and ambitious capital spending plans (remember
the 3G frenzy?), domestic demand slowed down very sharply, from 3.2% on average
in the 1998-2000 period to 0.9% on average in 2001-2003. Squeezed between debt
and deflation, companies cut capital spending and as well as headcount, wealthy
consumers were hit by stock market debacles and wage earners were scared about
their jobs. Since then, corporate restructuring has gone far and fast, and
companies are in better position to anticipate the recovery, increase spending
and, in some cases, start to hire workers. In addition, the rise of the euro
since late 2002 is a lasting powerful disinflationary force, to the benefit of
consumers. We expect consumer spending, which already surprised on the upside
in 2003 (1.3%), to accelerate further to 2% in 2004, thanks to stable labor
market conditions, stronger purchasing power stemming from lower inflation (not
higher wages) and, last but not least, income tax cuts in Germany and France
worth €17 billion or 0.3% of GDP.
Euro and corporate debt will cap the capex recovery
We are not as sanguine about the next large component of
domestic demand, i.e., investment. Sure, capex will recover in 2004, as new
investment opportunities stem from stronger demand and better profits. This
has already started, according to our proprietary European Analysts Survey, which,
in its December edition, confirmed that large companies have already started to
upgrade investment plans. However, the capex cycle will be constrained by the
strength of the currency, which will translate into lower profitability, and
the necessity to reduce further the debt overhang from which large companies
linked to the telecom sector are still suffering. As soon as the euphoria
created by the acceleration of growth in the US and Europe is over, we fear
that the complacency still prevailing in credit markets might be replaced by
scare. Then, over-leveraged companies would have to refrain from investing as
much as they would like to. With operating profits, measured by the gross
operating surplus, up 2.6%, we believe that the traditional recovery script,
marked by double-digit capex growth, is not the most likely one: Whereas the
so-called accelerator effects are likely to kick in, the other key factor for
capex decisions, profitability, is not strong enough. On balance, we see
corporate investment up 3% next year, after a 7% contraction in 2002-2003.
Exiting the zero real interest-rate policy
In many respects, the economic and market environment
facing the ECB now is the exact mirror image of the environment it faced a year
ago. Back then, the imminent threat of a war in Iraq, plunging equity markets
and a weakening global economy were weighing heavily on the growth outlook and
pushed inflation expectations lower. Consequently, the ECB slashed interest
rates by a total of 125 basis points between December 2002 and June 2003. Now,
a strong global economy and buoyant equity markets point to a decent economic
recovery, and bond markets have moved to price in inflation above the ECB 2%
ceiling in the longer term. Consequently, we expect the ECB to end its policy
of zero real interest rates — which was entirely appropriate in the zero real
GDP growth environment of 2003 — and to start nudging policy rates higher
during 2004.
Watch excess liquidity, the euro and politics
As we see it, provided that the economic recovery proceeds
roughly as described above, the timing and the extent of the monetary
tightening will be largely shaped by the interplay of three factors: (1) the
need to mop up some of the excess liquidity that the ECB has pumped into markets
before it starts to spill over into prices; (2) the unpredictable gyrations of
the euro’s external value; and (3) the potential impact on inflation
expectations from the suspension of the Stability and Growth Pact (SGP) and
from any political attempts to change the ECB’s mandate.
Money and credit growth will matter again
For more than two years now, the ECB has not only accepted
but — by cutting interest rates — actively nurtured M3 money supply growth well
in excess of the 4.5% reference value. Until recently, the Bank has argued
that excess liquidity was not a concern for price stability because strong M3
growth was partly due to temporary portfolio shifts into liquid assets,
reflecting high equity market volatility and declining stock prices between
2001 and mid-2003, and because the weak economic environment would keep price
pressures muted. However, with stock markets having risen sharply since the
spring and the economy now on the recovery path, the ECB is likely to become
increasingly concerned about a potential build-up of inflationary pressures
resulting from ample liquidity over the coming quarters. Thus, the stronger M3
growth remains and the more credit growth picks up in the upcoming economic
recovery, the earlier the ECB is likely to start tightening the monetary reins
again.
At least one eye on the euro
Another important factor determining the timing and the
extent of any monetary tightening in 2004 will be the gyrations of the euro.
Our currency team is looking for a further moderate appreciation of the euro in
the next few months, followed by a correction later in the year, which would
leave the euro’s trade-weighted index up some 3% in 2004 compared to the 2003
average. If the euro were to appreciate significantly more sharply over the
next few months, the ECB would likely react by reiterating that it is
interested not only in a “strong” but also a “stable” euro and by putting any
deliberations of an early rate hike on the back burner. Moreover, the ECB may
well decide to surprise markets by forex intervention if the euro rises too
fast, too soon. Conversely, a correction in the euro (which, given the almost
uniform consensus for a further appreciation, could be quite sharp) could
provide the trigger for an earlier-than-expected rate hike because it would be
seen by the ECB as adding to the upside risks for price stability over the
medium term.
The political wildcard
Third, but not least, the outlook for ECB monetary policy
is clouded by the emerging threat to Europe’s ‘stability culture’ from recent
political developments. First, the de-facto suspension of the SGP by the
ECOFIN softens the constraints on fiscal policy, which may well result in a
loosening of the fiscal policy stance in some member countries in the year(s)
ahead. If so, the ECB would have to consider this when setting its monetary
policy stance with a view to preserving price stability. Second, while initial
proposals that allow for the amendment of the ECB’s statute by a simplified
procedure (no longer requiring the ratification of changes to the ECB’s statute
by all national parliaments) were not included in the draft of the EU constitution,
some politicians (most prominently the Italian Premier Berlusconi) have
recently floated the idea of changing the ECB’s mandate to a Fed-type model
that would require the ECB to target not only inflation but also growth or
employment. Following the burial of the SGP, a broadening of this debate could
easily lead to a rise in long-term inflation expectations and would thus become
directly relevant to the ECB’s monetary policy decisions.
Moderate ECB tightening from the spring, unless the
euro overshoots
Taken together, with growth likely to surprise on the
upside in the next several months, inflation sticky at around 2%, liquidity abundant
and a conflict between the ECB and governments brewing, we expect the ECB to
start raising rates from the spring of this year. However, given the potential
upward pressure on the euro and the structural factors weighing on labor costs
and core inflation, we do not expect an aggressive tightening cycle. In total,
we see the refi rate rising by 75 basis points to 2.75% during 2004 and thus
less than halfway back towards what we deem a roughly neutral rate of 3.75% (2%
potential GDP growth plus a 1.75% inflation objective) for the euro area. Bond
yields should push higher during the first part of the year, testing the 5%
threshold at some stage, but should settle back close to what we deem as fair
value of around 4.75% during the second half. But again, if the euro were to
overshoot significantly, rate hikes would likely be postponed and, depending on
the impact on the economy and the inflation outlook, rate cuts might event reappear
on the agenda.
Mind the euro, global trade gyrations and interest
rates, but trust consumers
We see three main downside risks to our macro forecast.
First, our working assumption is an average euro/dollar exchange rate at $1.23
and, more importantly a 3% appreciation of the euro, on a trade-weighted
basis. In other terms, we have assumed that the spirit of the G-7 agreement in
Dubai would be respected. A lasting overshoot of the euro vis-à-vis the US
dollar and the yen would probably be fatal to our recovery scenario, and we
would not exclude a “triple dip”. Second, an early global trade downturn would
undermine business confidence before the recovery becomes self-sustainable.
Third, the loss of fiscal credibility might push long-term rates higher than
what we have assumed, harm the capex recovery and depress housing investment.
However, to end this outlook on a brighter note, we also see an upside risk to
growth: Consumers could be the trump card of the euro zone. As they get more
used to euro-denominated price tags, realize that inflation is declining and
that pension reforms are making their future less uncertain, they could well produce
a surprise by breaking open their piggy banks.
Important Disclosure Information at the end of this Forum
Euroland: Toward a Stability Pact, Version II
Eric Chaney (London)
At first
glance, Europe seemed to be in complete disarray
at the end of 2003, after the divisions provoked by the war in Iraq, the suspension of the Stability
and Growth Pact (SGP) and the failure to reach an agreement on the
Constitution. However, seen from a longer-term perspective, these events
look less salient. Just before the six founders of what are now the EU-15
initiated the negotiation of the Rome Treaty in 1954, a much deeper crisis had
shaken the continent, namely the failure of the European Defence Community, at
that time actively promoted by the US. For those who remember the
“empty chair” policy of General De Gaulle, or Lady Thatcher repeating at every
single meeting “I want my money back”, or, more recently, the apocalyptic
predictions that preceded the introduction of the euro, 2003 was, after all,
just an ordinary bad year for this European unification project Sir Winston
Churchill had described with almost perfect foresight in 1946.
Call it
optimism or stubbornly out-of-consensus thinking, but I believe that, in 2004,
there will be significant breakthroughs to make the EU more flexible and the
euro-area economy, more stable and growth-oriented. I will concentrate o
the latter point in this note. At the top of my agenda — but not yet at the
top of politicians’ — is the drafting of a sound Stability and Growth Pact. I
will call it SGP II.
The
Pact was neither economically sensible nor politically enforceable
In 2002,
when some politicians first considered ways to fudge the Pact, my position was:
better to comply with the Pact in a co-operative fashion than to let deficits
slip or try to change the Pact hastily (see The Arithmetics and Politics of
the Stability Pact, September 2, 2002). Political realities were
not favourable to these views and, in the end, the two heavyweights of the euro
club, Germany and France, chose the worse exit path.
Without acknowledging it, they let their deficits slip in 2003 and 2004
and, in the end, they orchestrated a diplomatic coup
to shelve the SGP, creating a dangerous judicial vacuum.
Before
going further, it is worth asking why these countries, which have a
long-standing culture of fiscal stability, as testified by their relatively low
level of public debt (in 2002, 60.8% for Germany and 59.1% for France), made such a choice. Beyond
political considerations, I believe that the answer is simply that the Pact was
neither economically sensible nor practically enforceable. Conceived by
Theo Waigel, then German finance minister, as a marketing tool designed to sell
the euro to a German public scared by the prospect of sharing its currency with
Italy, it was from the beginning a grossly pro-cyclical instrument.
By
pro-cyclical, I mean that in good times such as 1999-2000, the Pact did not
provide incentives to save for a rainy day, whereas in bad times such as
2002-2003, the enforcement of the Pact implied higher taxes and/or lower
spending, making the downturn even worse, as Portugal has learnt the hard
way. In 2002, Germany tried to respect the Pact. As
a result, the contraction of German domestic demand pulled most of the euro
zone into stagnation. Defenders of the Pact would probably argue that it
is just a question of precaution and that a balanced budget over the cycle
would prevent such fiscal misfortunes. This is wishful thinking in my
view. Swedish academics have calculated that for a country such as
theirs, where automatic stabilisers (i.e., taxes and government spending) are
high, it would be necessary to run a permanent surplus of 3% of GDP in order to
avoid reaching the -3% limit, would a downturn occur. I wonder if the
authors of the Pact have meditated on the political feasibility of running
permanent surpluses in democracies.
A new
Stability Pact is indispensable
To make a
long story short, the Pact fell victim to its built-in
flaws, and that should not be regretted from an economic standpoint.
However, clear fiscal rules are necessary in an economic area which does not
have the powerful shock absorber provided by fiscal federalism, as in the US, and does not want it. In
such a framework, there will always be a temptation to run free-rider fiscal
strategies in order to benefit from the low interest rates provided by the
currency union, without incurring sanctions from currency markets. This is all
the more important since the euro club will welcome many new members in the
next ten years. On which principles should an SGP II be founded? I see
three main guidelines to judge fiscal sustainability and correct potential
deviations.
Three
principles for a SGP II
1.
Retain the nominal anchors set up by the Maastricht Treaty, i.e., deficits
below 3% of GDP and debt below 60%. Arbitrary as they may appear (they
are not totally arbitrary, in fact, but that is another story), these values
have the great benefit of being well known by the public; also, they were
widely accepted by all during the EMU negotiation — having been technically
involved in that process, I do not remember serious quarrels about them.
However, SGP I has demonstrated that these ceilings must not be taken
rigidly. In fact, the words “reference value” used in the Maastricht
Treaty should be preferred to the word “ceiling” associated
to the famous “Drei Komma Nul” trumpeted by Theo Waigel in 1997.
2.
Take into consideration both initial debt levels and trend growth rates.
In good theory, fiscal sustainability is about stocks (i.e., debts), not
flows (i.e., deficits). This is also how markets would rate issuers of
debt in the corporate and sovereign worlds. Clearly, Finland, with a debt of 42.7% of GDP in
2002, or the Netherlands (52.6%) should not be treated
similarly to Italy (106.7%) or Belgium (105.3%). Equally, the trend
growth rate of each country should be one of the parameters used when judging
fiscal positions. A temporary rise of the public debt in a high-growth
country, say Spain for example, is less destabilizing
than in a slow-growth one, such as Germany. Similarly, the public
pension liabilities that national accounts cannot take into account should be
added to the traditional debt estimates.
3.
To keep structural deficits in check, enforce a spending target rule. The
main flaw of SGP I was its pro-cyclical nature. In economic jargon, SGP I
did not let automatic stabilisers play freely, i.e., did not let cyclical
deficits increase in bad times, nor forced governments to let cyclical surplus
grow in good times. The best way to restore the full use of automatic
stabilisers is to agree on public spending growth targets and have these
targets respected. If, for instance, GDP growth unexpectedly dropped
below trend, then the cyclical deficit would automatically rise, as tax
receipts would decline. As long as the government would respect its
spending growth target, this should not be a problem, even if its deficit
exceeded 3% of GDP. If, on the contrary, GDP growth accelerated above
trend, tax receipts would naturally grow fatter and generate surpluses, as long
as public entities respect spending targets. The irresistible political
pressure to “spend the surplus” would be eliminated by the respect of the
spending rule. In addition, spending is easy to monitor and check,
whereas tax receipts are so notoriously volatile than even national Treasuries
cannot accurately forecast them. Hence, the spending rule has the double
advantage of being stabilizing and pragmatic.
For
aging countries, spending targets must be below trend growth
However
the spending target rule is established economically, it leaves open the most
difficult question: What should this target be? From an economic
standpoint, in a region where populations are rapidly aging (Spain, Italy and Germany being at the forefront), most
countries (not all), should aim at reducing the size of their debt relative to
their GDP. This implies that nominal spending targets should, in most
cases, be lower than trend nominal GDP growth and, in the case of highly
indebted countries, significantly lower, in order to guarantee a
self-sustainable reduction of the debt. I guess that the most difficult
part of any negotiation would be to agree on spending targets, based on
propositions made by the Commission. I know that most governments would
be reluctant to accept such constraints on their fiscal sovereignty.
However, since the spending rule would reduce the natural pro-cyclicality of
fiscal policies and thus give more freedom to governments, reaching an
agreement should not be as difficult as it looks. Note that countries
wanting to reduce their own tax burden in order to foster long-term growth
would be free to set their own spending targets below the rule commonly agreed.
I have
left aside many important aspects of what should make SGP II a success.
How to decide and implement sanctions is certainly one of them. In
addition, public spending items that generate significant externalities, such
as environment or defence, do not necessarily qualify for the spending
rule. I leave these issues for another forum. A more important
question remains: Will the political environment push the Commission and
governments to review their copy and work on a serious and sound Stability and
Growth Pact, Version II?
The
negotiation will start in one of the next three EU presidencies
In a
better world, the EU Commission would have anticipated the events that led to
the suspension of the Pact on November 25 and proposed a renegotiation before
being defeated by a coup orchestrated by the four big states (yes, Italy and
Britain were part of the plot). This did not happen, unfortunately.
However, 55 years of European negotiations in peacetime demonstrate that good
things normally emerge from bad experiments, and it is not too late to start
doing the right things, given the complacency I still see in bond
markets. Most policy makers, although not all, are convinced that the
Pact will have to be reworked, the most important exception being the European
Central Bank which, it must be reminded, has no mandate concerning fiscal policies.
My hope and my conviction is that reason will prevail and that, in one of the
next three six-month presidencies, i.e., the Irish, Dutch and Luxembourg ones,
the real work will start. During the course of 2004, I am convinced that
fiscal issues will attract a lot of attention in financial markets and that
cynical views such as “the SGP is dead, let’s forget it” will not help in
making optimal investment decisions.
Important Disclosure Information at the end of this Forum
Europe - All: Disunited We Stand
Joachim Fels (London)
At the height of the Iraq war back in March, I wrote a note
arguing that the idea of an ever-closer political union culminating in the
United States of Europe always was and would always remain just a pipe dream (see
The Dis-United States of Europe, March 24, 2003). At that time, the public
debate was dominated by the discord between “old” and “new” Europe on the involvement in Iraq. But I argued that this was only one
of several political dividing lines within Europe, which would become increasingly apparent over time. However, I had
no idea that this issue would come to the fore with a vengeance already in the
final two months of 2003, when the de facto burial of the Stability and Growth
Pact (SGP) caused a major rift between governments and when the EU Summit on
the proposed EU Constitution failed miserably. With hindsight, 2003 was the
year when serious cracks in the European political compound became apparent.
Looking ahead, I believe 2004 could be the year when markets begin to price in
some of dire consequences of the Disunited States of Europe — the return of the
country factor in bond markets; the weakened position of the ECB, which might
be pressurized into producing higher inflation; and a higher risk of EU
secession and EMU break-up.
Conflict over fiscal policy is here to
stay
As I see it, the conflict over fiscal
policy and the SGP that erupted in 2003 is unlikely to go away anytime soon. Many
of the small countries (plus Spain) that have pursued a more virtuous budgetary policy in the past
several years are seriously angered by the slippage in budget deficits in large
countries such as Germany and France. This is because rising budget
deficits in the large countries, due to their sheer size, are seen as raising
the borrowing costs for all governments within EMU, irrespective of the
consolidation efforts that the smaller countries have made. It is important to
note that the SGP was suspended exactly at the point when the EU Commission
proposed to make binding recommendations on fiscal policy to Germany and France. This underscores the basic fact that the larger member states are
simply unwilling to accept any serious interference in their sovereignty over
national fiscal policy. It is difficult to see how a re-writing of the fiscal
rules, now being discussed widely, could overcome this basic fact. In any
case, devising and negotiating a new SGP is a matter of years, not months, and
even if a new, better Pact could be agreed upon, it would hardly be credible,
given the sobering experience with the old Pact. In my view, it might be
better to do away with any attempts to coordinate and restrain fiscal policy on
a euro-wide basis altogether and rely on national electorates and
discriminating bond markets (helped by rating agencies) to punish fiscally
profligate national governments. I will come back to this point below.
Battles about redistribution ahead
Another area of discord, as illustrated
by the failed EU Summit last week, is the distribution of voting rights and
thus the distribution of power in an enlarged EU of 25 members. The Summit
failed because Spain and Poland were unwilling to give up the
disproportionately high number of votes (relative to the size of their
population) accorded to them in the Nice treaty several years ago — both so far
have 27 votes against 29 votes for the four largest countries. The deeper
issue here is, of course, that the voting influence will be crucial for them
(and other members) in the upcoming battle about a new key for the distribution
of EU agricultural and structural funds in EU-25. These negotiations about the
EU budget for the seven-year period starting in 2007 will kick off in 2005 at
the latest. Presently, it looks unlikely that the EU Constitution can be
agreed upon before late 2004, and even that is uncertain. The longer this
process drags on, the more likely it is that the negotiations on the
Constitution will be complicated further by the upcoming re-distributional
struggle about EU funds. Thus, the present draft Constitution may turn out to
be just that forever — a draft.
Disunited we stand
All of these dividing lines in Europe serve to illustrate an important
point: Europe is unlikely to
move closer to the EU founding fathers’ ideal of a United States of Europe in
the foreseeable future. Decision-making in an enlarged EU of 25 members, with
the current rules in place, will be highly complicated, and there are plenty of
areas where member states simply won’t be able to agree. Thus, from a political
point of view, question marks will continue to hang over how effectively the
European Union will be able to operate in the future.
Diversity should be bullish for
competition and growth
From an economic point of view, however,
a diverse union may not be such a bad thing after all. As I see it, Europe’s political, cultural and economic
diversity has always been a strength rather than a weakness as it provides for
a healthy competition of political economic and systems catering to their local
voters and to internationally mobile companies. Yes, this kind of competition
may look messy or even chaotic at times, some countries may run in the wrong
direction for a while, and internal disagreements and even institutional crises
in the EU will ebb and flow. However, as long as the common market for goods,
services, capital and people rules, this kind of competition should produce
better economic outcomes than a single government for the whole union, which
would be far detached from its diverse citizens in 25 or more member states (I
first laid out this argument in an article in the Financial Times on December
22, 1997 entitled “One Money, but Many Nations”). Countries that pursue the
right tax, welfare and labour market policies in this set-up will be rewarded
with capital inflows, stronger growth and lower unemployment and will serve as
a role model for others that are doing less well. Eventually, the process of
“dynamic benchmarking” will lift the boat for all members willing and able to
play the game and should result in a less regulated and faster-growing European
economy. Hence my optimism on the long-term growth prospects for Greater
Europe.
The return of the country factor
The prospect of a disunited and diverse
EU has some important consequences for financial markets, however. First, the
country factor is likely to become more important again in determining bond
and, possibly, equity prices. Growing divisions on budgetary policy and the de
facto burial of the SGP could lead to a significant widening of government bond
yield spreads between the more and the less virtuous countries. Partly, this
would reflect the actual fiscal policy divergences and partly it would reflect
the markets’ assessment that a financial bailout for a member state running
into serious fiscal difficulties will be less likely in a disunited Europe. In thinking about the potential
for a widening of bond yield spreads between national markets, it is important
to keep two points in mind: First, by joining the euro, national governments
have given up the option to resort to the printing press in order to finance
deficits. This would only be possible again if a country decided to leave EMU
or if the ECB could be pressurized into printing money to bail out a government.
Second, the “no bail out clause” in the Maastricht treaty stipulates that no member state can be forced to step in for
the obligations of another member state. Both provisions together imply that,
in theory, the credit quality of a fiscally profligate country could
deteriorate quite significantly (to illustrate at the risk of exaggerating,
think of European government bonds as the equivalent to municipal bonds in the
US) and could lead to a significant widening of government bond yield spreads
with more fiscally virtuous member states.
Pressures for higher inflation
Second, a disunited Europe won’t make the job for the ECB any
easier. While the ECB has no policy instrument to address economic divergence
between the euro participants, a growing divergence of budgetary and general
economic policies would likely lead to increased political pressures for an
easier monetary policy to grease the wheels. Whether the independent ECB would
cave in to such pressures is uncertain. Yet history shows that even the most
independent central banks are not immune to the political environment in which
they operate. Thus, my guess is that a disunited Europe would, over the longer haul lead to higher inflation in the euro
area.
The risk of E(M)U break-up
Third, in this changed environment,
markets will have to attach a higher probability to a break-up of EMU and/or
the EU at some future date. While I believe that the economic benefits from
participating in both are sufficiently large to make such an event unlikely, we
simply cannot neglect the possibility of fraction and secession any more. In
my view, as the economic divisions within Europe are likely to become larger rather than smaller in the future,
investors should start to factor in this risk. These worries — an inflationary
outcome coupled with a heightened risk of E(M)U break-up — lie at the heart of
my very contrarian view on the euro, which I personally expect to trade
significantly lower than presently in 6-12 months time, and they contribute to
my bearish view on European bonds both in absolute terms and relative to US
bonds.
Important Disclosure Information at the end of this Forum
Europe - All: Merging Europe
Riccardo Barbieri Hermitte & Elga Bartsch (London)
The
2004 EU enlargement is more significant politically, and in its effects on EU
governance, than economically.
With
the accession of 10 new countries to the European Union, less than half
a year away, enlargement is bound to become one of the defining themes in
2004 and beyond. The failure to agree on a new constitution at the
Brussels EU summit in mid-December underscores the fact that
streamlining the decision-making process and reducing the over-representation
of small countries will be among the biggest challenges (see Joachim Fels's comment Disunited We Stand in this issue).
Impact on GDP growth likely to
be small in the EU-15 ...
Empirical
studies suggest that the cumulative effect of enlargement on real GDP in the
EU-15 by the end of the decade is likely to be an increase of less than
1%. However, we believe that enlargement will increase the pressure
towards economic and labour market reform in the EU. In addition, the
effect is likely to be larger in those countries that are more affected by the
flow of goods, investment and labour vis-à-vis the 10 accession countries
(AC-10) — Germany and Austria in particular.
... but
potentially large in the accession countries.
Some
of the benefits from EU accession were brought forward by a surge in bilateral
foreign trade and inward foreign direct investment (FDI) during the second half
of the 1990s. Going forward, the impact on investment and productivity
growth will still be significant, in our view. Income convergence is
likely, albeit not guaranteed. It depends crucially on the ability of the
accession countries to leverage the EU funds and to maintain exchange rate
competitiveness and relatively sound public finances. Should these conditions
be fulfilled, we would expect the four central European countries (Czech Republic, Hungary, Poland and Slovakia) to experience an average
real GDP growth rate of 4.2% in 2004-2010.
Trade and investment linkages
with the EU to deepen.
The
degree of foreign trade and investment integration between the EU-15 and the
accession countries is already high, thanks to increased
vertical integration within industries and low labour costs and access to local
markets. Post accession, the adoption of the single market and the recent
elimination of residual tariff barriers by the AC-10 will probably lead to a
further increase in trade. While inward FDI as a share of GDP may not
sustain the peaks of 2000-2001, it is nevertheless likely to remain high, as higher
income levels open new local market opportunities and European medium-sized
companies gain confidence.
Migration flows will initially
be small, but they will grow in the next decade.
Free
movement of labour from the AC-10 to the EU-15 will be restricted during a
seven-year transition period. Once the
restrictions are lifted, we reckon that the inflow of workers from central
Europe is unlikely to exceed 0.4% per annum of the EU-15 labour force, due in
part to a decrease in the per capita income gap between the existing and the
new EU member states. That said, the immigration
flows are likely to be more meaningful in Germany, due to geographic proximity
with the AC-10.
Enlargement will pose a
challenge for the ECB, but not necessarily through higher interest rates.
If the AC-10 were to adopt the euro relatively early,
that would impart an inflationary bias and make it more difficult for the ECB
to achieve its “below but close to 2%” inflation target. The experience of the
existing euro zone points to higher inflation rates in countries with
relatively lower per capita income. The same can be expected to occur in
central Europe. However, enlargement
should also make the product and labour markets of the EU more competitive,
which could lower the average euro zone inflation rate and pave the way for
lower interest rates. Secondly, the ECB is likely to continue to focus on
the weighted average inflation rates in the euro area. Given the
relatively low relative weight of the AC-10, the effect on ECB policy may be
limited.
EU institutions insist that
the AC-10 not rush to adopt the euro.
The
European Commission, the ECB and member states have urged the AC-10 to make
further progress on economic convergence and
structural reforms before joining the single currency. We think even the
current pressure to reform the Stability Pact should not be viewed as a sign
that euro applicants would be excused for not satisfying the fiscal convergence
criteria.
High budget deficits are the
main hurdle, but fiscal consolidation is likely to be gradual.
EU
accession should lead to increased government outlays in the AC-10 in the form
of public investment and contributions to the EU budget.
Meanwhile, tax revenues risk being curtailed by increased corporate tax
competition among the central European countries and political pressure for
lower personal income taxes. With higher indirect taxes the only partial
offset, fiscal consolidation is likely to proceed gradually, relying primarily
on the fiscal dividend of faster economic growth.
While some smaller AC-10 may
adopt the euro in 2007, larger ones will probably wait until the end of this
decade.
Given
their current fiscal, inflation and exchange rate positions, it is conceivable
that Slovenia, Cyprus and the Baltic Republics could adopt
the euro in January 2007. Hungary has a 2008 target, which we
believe has more than a 50% probability of being realised.
Our best guesses on the other countries are 2009 for Poland and 2010 for the Czech Republic and Slovakia. That said, if strong economic growth is achieved in 2004-06, that
could create greater political momentum to adopt the euro in 2008 in all four
central European countries.
Important Disclosure Information at the end of this Forum
Euroland: New EU Entrants — Making Their Presence Felt
Oliver Weeks (London)
Ahead of
their May 1 accession, the EU's ten new members are already making their
presence felt politically. Poland's
role in the acrimonious collapse of the EU's constitutional negotiations
underlines that it remains unlikely to take up President Jacques Chirac's
recommendation that the applicants should know their place. Many of the
smaller new entrants also appear uncomfortable with an integration plan
perceived as favouring the larger states. Economically we think the
outlook for the major applicants remains bright in the short term, more because
of the incipient Euroland recovery than because of any changes brought by EU
entry. Rising political tensions risk slightly reducing the promised
increase in redistribution to eastern Europe after
2007, and further delaying the entry of the larger central European states to
the euro, but the convergence story is not entirely off the rails.
Further
indications that Euroland recovery is under way bode well for central European
growth and current accounts in 2004. With a strong EUR/USD, EU industrial
production surprising on the upside, an eighth successive monthly rise in the
IFO business survey, and at least partial agreement on German tax reform, the
external environment for the CE4 looks the most favourable since 2000. We
expect the Czech Republic and Hungary, the most
exposed to the Euroland cycle, to be able to maintain output growth just as
indirect tax and administered price rises squeeze real household income
growth. In Poland
and Slovakia,
we see more upside for domestic demand but presently low current-account
deficits leave room for sustainable expansion. The combination of EU
recovery and EU entry should see a recovery in direct investment into the
region as easier border crossings make the region more attractive to smaller
investors and outsourcers. With slightly easier labour movement, Poland
in particular is likely to benefit from growing remittances. We see room
for a resumption of currency strength in Poland
and Slovakia
next year, both of which look likely to take an increasing share of inward FDI,
and to remain the fastest-growing economies in the CE4.
The most
widely anticipated change next year, access to EU structural and agricultural
funds, is unlikely to be significant in the short term, unless in disappointing
inflated popular expectations. We do not expect net transfers from the EU
to exceed 0.5% of GDP in central Europe next year, rising to a maximum of 1.2%
of GDP in Poland by 2006 on the optimistic assumption that Poland meets the
related administrative requirements. Under the EU's 2007–12 budget
new members will have been hoping to move up towards the 2–2.5% of GDP
net transfers currently enjoyed by Greece
and Portugal.
With the failure of the constitutional talks, it will now be harder to separate
the issues of financing and voting power, with net EU contributors more
determined to limit the cost of being outvoted by the major recipients.
The Spanish-Polish alliance may prove short-lived in this area, but we would
expect Spain to suffer more than Poland from any move to limit overall EU
spending. From the German government's point of view, it may look both
cheaper and fairer to satisfy Poland's
aid aspirations.
Other
areas that could be threatened by further large/small member acrimony or a move
to a two-speed Europe include further waves of EU and Euro-area
enlargement. The Balkans already risk delaying EU membership with the
election of a post-fascist government in Croatia and a likely nationalist
victory in Serbia. Similarly on Euro entry, while it will be hard to
argue that the Baltic states or Slovenia do not meet early entry criteria,
fiscal developments in Poland, the Czech Republic, and Hungary have only helped
the case of those on the current EU side who may prefer to see the CE4 delaying
membership. The ECB and EC have reserved substantial discretion on the
interpretation of exchange rate stability criteria. While in the past
this discretion has tended to favour the applicants there is a risk this may
not be the case in the current political environment. The collapse of the
Stability and Growth Pact may also reinforce doubts over entry among both
current EMU 'outs' and eurosceptics in countries like the Czech Republic,
particularly as the Maastricht entry conditions will not be relaxed. In
the CE4 we continue to expect the 2005-6 round of
parliamentary elections to take priority in the short term over the fiscal
tightening needed for early EMU entry.
Yet the
outlook is by no means all gloomy. Hungary appears to be making use of
2004's political window to move further towards fiscal tightening. While
the current Polish government appears to be in extended death throes, we
believe a PO-PiS led government is likely to be able to use a still-strong
growth environment to begin tightening in 2005. Despite rising inflation,
we expect rate cuts to resume or continue in 2004 in Hungary, Poland and
Slovakia, particularly with currency appreciation in the latter two. It
is harder to be optimistic on Czech interest rates, with Euro entry this decade
still highly unlikely, but a likely move to Eurobond issuance should help keep
funding relatively cheap. While the market exuberance that followed the
EU's Copenhagen
summit this time last year is unlikely to be repeated, and rising Euroland
rates will provide a challenging backdrop, we believe there are still
opportunities in convergence.
Important Disclosure Information at the end of this Forum
United Kingdom: A Balancing Act
Joachim Fels & Melanie Baker (London)
For many years, the UK economy has benefited from the
tailwinds of market-oriented reform in the 1980s and early 1990s, as well as
from the shift to a more credible monetary regime, which led to a permanent
decline in interest rates. However, with interest rates now on the rise and
the government shifting resources from the private into the public sector,
consumer spending is unlikely to remain the driver of growth in 2004 and
beyond, in our view. Our main case is that external demand and investment are
likely to take over as the engines of growth. However, the risk is that this
rebalancing will not succeed and that the economic recovery will sputter. Well
aware of this, and with CPI inflation well below the new 2% target, the Bank of
England is likely to tread cautiously in 2004.
The success story continues
UK GDP growth returned to an above-trend
rate in the third quarter of 2003 and looks set to maintain this pace into
2004, in our view, when we see GDP expanding by 2.7%, compared with our 2003
estimate of 2.0%. Looking back over the past year, the UK economy has exhibited an impressive
degree of resilience in the face of weak equity markets and geopolitical
turbulence, especially when compared with its European peers. As we see it,
there are three reasons for the UK’s economic outperformance. First, a buoyant housing market
encouraged and enabled consumers to maintain a pace of spending above the
growth rate of real disposable income. This trend was reinforced by the Bank
of England’s rate reductions in February and July, which fuelled household debt
accumulation further. Second, fiscal policy continued to be expansionary, with
the structural general government deficit widening by about 1 percentage point
of GDP in 2003. And third, sterling weakened by about 4% on a trade-weighted
basis during the first half of the year, providing a fillip for the
manufacturing sector, which emerged from a multi-year recession during the
year.
Successful rebalancing crucial for
continued growth
Looking into 2004, we see a very
different combination of factors propelling economic growth. While some of
this year’s policy stimulus is still in the pipeline and will provide momentum
going into 2004, fiscal policy is likely to be at best slightly expansionary in
2004, the Bank of England looks set gradually to remove the monetary stimulus,
and sterling is likely to be stronger rather than weaker (our currency team is
forecasting a 4% appreciation of the trade-weighted index in 2004). Moreover,
we assume a gradual cooling of the housing market boom that is likely to make
consumers more cautious and should lead to a further slowing of household
spending growth to around 2% in real terms in 2004. The new drivers of growth
in 2004 will be exports and capex, we think. Export growth should benefit from
the pick-up in world trade growth and from the gain in price competitiveness
due to sterling’s depreciation earlier this year. The same factors should help
produce a recovery in corporate investment. The outlook is therefore for more
balanced economic growth in 2004 compared with the past few years, with
consumer spending slowing and exports and investment gathering steam. This
should also be accompanied by a narrowing of the gap between a bubbling
services sector and an ailing manufacturing sector over the coming year.
Underwhelmed by household debt
The continued rise in private household
debt and its potential implications for consumer spending are likely to remain
the key issue for UK financial
markets in 2004. With the debt level mounting to a record high, many observers
have concluded that the UK
consumer is ‘an accident waiting to happen’. We disagree. The demographic
trend towards increasing owner-occupation rates, the (permanent) decline in
interest rates due to a more credible monetary policy regime, rising household
assets, and a more competitive credit market go a long way in explaining the
increase in debt-to-income ratios. And, despite higher ratios of mortgage
equity withdrawal, un-drawn housing equity as a percentage of total housing
equity has risen to more than 75% as housing wealth increases have outpaced the
rise in mortgage debt. Clearly, higher interest rates will eat into consumer’s
purchasing power. However, to push debt servicing costs as a share of
disposable income (close to historic lows right now) anywhere close to the high
levels seen during the early 1990s housing bust and recession, we estimate that
the Bank of England would have to raise rates to around 8% — hardly a realistic
presumption, in our view. In short, while high debt levels will be a factor
weighing on consumer spending in a rising interest rate environment, they are
unlikely to spell disaster for the UK economy.
The bigger risk: sterling and the
global economy
The bigger risk to our benign outlook for
a rebalancing of UK growth, in
our view, emerges from external developments. Should the global economic
recovery falter yet again, or should sterling appreciate very sharply, the transition
to export-led and capex-led UK
growth would not materialise. Further, as the Bank of England would likely
keep rates lower than otherwise or even cut them again in such an environment,
private household borrowing and spending would be stimulated further, risking
an unsustainable boom in consumer spending followed by a bust at a later
stage.
More rate hikes, but no overkill
Another key theme for UK markets in 2004 is the speed and extent
of further base rate increases. In our view, rather than hiking rates
aggressively as it did in past tightening cycles, the Bank of England will
tread cautiously in raising interest rates, for three reasons. First, the
Monetary Policy Committee (MPC) is concerned about the build-up of household
debt. Given the uncertainty about the distribution of debt among households,
the Bank is concerned that, despite the relatively low average level of debt
servicing costs, aggressive rate hikes could lead to a sharp retrenchment of
consumer spending by certain highly indebted groups of households. Second,
although most business surveys portray a smart recovery in the manufacturing
sector, manufacturing output, exports and capex have all disappointed
recently. Given the still-fragile state of the manufacturing recovery, the
Bank will not want to risk a strong sterling appreciation, which could result
from faster rate hikes. And third, despite record-low unemployment, wage
pressures have remained relatively subdued in the private sector so far,
suggesting that the link between resource utilisation, wages and prices might
have changed. Moreover, there is a possibility that the recent change in the
bank’s inflation remit to a CPI inflation target of 2% from the old 2.5% RPIX
inflation target will change the public’s inflation expectations and thus
dampen wage demands. While, as we explain below, this would be entirely
unwarranted, such a reaction cannot be excluded a priori.
A higher inflation target in disguise
The change in the Bank’s inflation remit
to a 2% target for the CPI (the index formerly known as HICP) from a 2.5%
target for the RPIX is more than a technical change, in our view. While
looking like a reduction in the inflation target on the surface, a 2% CPI
target is roughly equivalent to a 2.8% RPIX target and thus implies a higher
rather than a lower sighting shot for inflation. This is because the long-run
difference between the RPIX and HICP inflation measures is around 0.8
percentage points (pp), with 0.5 pp resulting from a different method used to
aggregate individual prices and 0.3 pp largely resulting from the long-run
trend in house prices (which are excluded from the CPI, but are included in the
RPIX via the housing depreciation component). Thus, the new target implies
that the Bank of England will have to keep monetary policy slightly more
expansionary for some time in order to engineer the transition to what is a de
facto higher long-run inflation rate. This is yet another reason why we think
the Bank will nudge up rates fairly cautiously during 2004.
Important Disclosure Information at the end of this Forum
United Kingdom: Slower Consumer Spending, But Rate Hikes No Disaster
Melanie Baker (London)
Some
have suggested that rate hikes spell disaster for the UK consumer — that with
the UK consumer heavily indebted,
increases in interest rates could push household spending over the edge. While we look for the UK consumer to continue to slow
in 2004, we do not share the view that Bank of England rate hikes spell
disaster. In our view, the Bank would
need to hike rates to somewhere near 8% (from 3.75% currently) to approach
“danger levels.” This does
not seem realistic to us.
Consumer to slow.
We
look for 2.1% growth in household final consumption in 2004, after 2.3% growth
in 2003 and following actual consumption growth of 3.6% in 2002. We see several factors driving this slowdown
into 2004, including a gradual cooling of the housing market boom and monetary
policy tightening from the Bank of England.
Previous spending
‘busts’ triggered by rate hikes.
We
look for a further 75bp in rate hikes in 2004, having seen a first 25bp hike in
November already. These rate hikes would
dent consumer spending by raising the amount of money UK households spend servicing
their debt. Given, however, that the
UK’s last “bust” in household spending in the late 80s/early
90s was triggered by massive rate hikes, it is key to consider just how
sensitive to rate hikes the UK consumer is likely to be this time around. Given high household debt levels (at 88% of
GDP, compared to a ratio of 75% in 1990 and euro area levels closer to 60%),
some make the case that rate hikes could send the UK consumer over the edge.
But rate cycle will likely be
less aggressive and debt service looks manageable.
The
UK’s rate hiking cycle is unlikely to be
aggressive, and is certainly unlikely to be as aggressive as in the late 80s
(when rates were hiked from 8.5% in 1988 to 15% in 1990). Further, debt servicing is currently at very low
and manageable levels, in our view, such that it would take quite an increase
in rates to reach the kind of danger levels seen in the 1980s. To try to quantify the impact on debt service
we took two approaches:
1) Debt service ratio
‘danger level’ would need rates at 8%.
In
the late 1980s, the ratio of interest payments to disposable income reached
highs of 15% in 1990. We are currently
at levels of around 7%. Using the
assumption that disposable income grows a conservative 0.6%Q through end-2004
and that household debt continues to grow at a substantial pace despite the
rate hikes (we assume 3.0%Q), by end-2004 our ratio
would be at only around 9.3% on our rate-hike assumptions. In fact, to reach 15%, on the income and debt
assumptions above, we would need to see interest rates rise to just over
8%. While not inconceivable, with
interest rates currently at 3.75%, with growth around trend, and with inflation
some 0.7pp below target, it seems very unlikely to us.
2) Increased debt service
would not take an unmanageable slice of average disposable income.
We
calculate that average net household financial liabilities are around £39,420
per UK household. A 100bp increase in the interest rate paid on
debt would thus raise interest payments by some £394 a year. This extra payment amounts to around 1.3% of
household disposable income. However,
note that this calculation assumes all borrowing is floating rate, so this may
be an overestimate. Hence, while such a
repo rate increase would put a dent in consumer spending,
any effect should be relatively limited on an aggregate economy basis. Further, the kind of economic environment we
see justifying 100bp in rate hikes would be one where above-trend growth
generates additional disposable income via employment growth and higher wages,
again suggesting consumer spending would be unlikely to crash.
Highly indebted groups may
suffer, but this could help the Bank stay cautious.
The
risk we see is that certain highly indebted groups of households will be very
adversely affected by moderate rate hikes and that these households may also be
responsible for a disproportionate degree of consumer spending growth. November’s sharp slowdown in retail
sales volumes might even be taken as early evidence of this by some. However, the Bank of England appears to be
conscious of this risk. In the November
MPC minutes the need to be cautious on raising rates due to uncertainty on the
response in consumption was highlighted.
Hence, the existence of such indebted groups would anyway be one further
reason to look for nothing further than a gentle rate hike profile from the
Bank.
Bottom line.
“Disaster
scenarios” for UK consumer spending look
unrealistic to us without aggressive rate hikes. One risk might be the existence of highly
indebted groups of influential consumers.
However, the existence of such groups would, in itself, help ensure only
a gentle path for rate hikes.
Important Disclosure Information at the end of this Forum
Germany: Beware Reform Fatigue
Elga Bartsch (London)
Nach dem Spiel ist vor dem
Spiel.
Sepp
Herberger (German National Soccer Coach 1936 to 1964)
2004 will
mark the fiftieth anniversary of Germany winning its first soccer world cup
after the Second World War. In a cliffhanger final in Switzerland on July 4,
1954 --
later dubbed ‘the miracle of Bern’ — the German team beat Hungary 3-2 (for details see http://www.wunder-von-bern.de/).
The victory came as a momentous event for postwar Germany. In fact, some
historians view it as ‘the true date of birth’ for the Federal Republic of
Germany. Fifty years on, the comments made by the coach of the German
team, Sepp Herberger, after the spectacular victory are an apt description of
the challenges facing the German economy over the next 12
months. Herberger reminded players that ‘after the game is before the
game’, adding that ‘the next game is always the hardest’. In my view,
exactly the same applies to progress of reform in Germany: To paraphrase the legendary German
coach: After the reform is before the reform. And the next reform
is always the hardest.
It was
only in late December that a compromise was reached over which measures of the
government’s ambitious reform agenda to implement on January 1,
2004.
Despite the income tax cuts eventually agreed on, at €15 billion or 0.7% of
GDP, being slightly smaller than previously envisaged, we still expect the
economy to expand at an above-trend rate of 2.1% in 2004. But together
with the stronger euro exchange rate and a potential slowdown of the Chinese
economy, the scaled-down income tax cuts could shift the balance of risks to
our forecast to the downside. That said, the downside risks should be
relatively small — accounting for up to two-tenths of a percentage point, on
our estimates. In addition, with the remaining income tax cuts now
becoming effective in 2005, a similar upside risk arises to our 1.8% GDP growth
forecast for that period. If our 2004 GDP turns out be to close to the
mark, next year could mark the end of Germany’s multi-year underperformance
vis-à-vis its neighbours. Yet such a vigorous recovery might in fact pose
a risk to the longer-term growth outlook for Europe’s largest economy.
Having
been bombarded with an unprecedented number of reform proposals this fall, the
public — and even more so their elected representatives — start to show first
signs of reform fatigue. A robust cyclical recovery might give rise to
the illusion that enough reforms have been implemented to revive the economy on
a lasting basis. This could not be further from the truth. There
can be no mistaking that Germany’s ailing economy needs further
reforms to raise the rate of its potential (or trend) output growth.
Instead of waiting for the next multi-year mini-recession to push through with
additional reforms, the government might want to use the tailwinds of cyclical
upswing to get additional reforms under way. Pressures for improvements
in the cost-competitiveness of the German economy will likely come from both a
stronger euro and from EU enlargement, which will add ten new countries to the single
market in May of next year. In my view, rising to these competitive
challenges requires a more flexible job market and more moderate labour cost
increases. Contrary to many other countries, in Germany the government must not interfere
with the bilateral negotiations between the trade unions and the employer
federations on wages, benefits and working conditions. However, the
government can change the institutional framework under which these
negotiations take place.
On my
report card of German labour market reforms, there are still three to-do items.
First, the government should provide a clear legal framework for so-called
opening clauses, which would allow individual companies to deviate from
industry-wide contracts. Unfortunately, the government resisted pressure
from the opposition parties in the recent mediation talks to legally enforce
such clauses, hoping that the negotiating parties would voluntarily agree on the
clauses. If these hopes turn out to be misplaced, legislative action
would be required. Second, the Guenstigkeitsprinzip,
which stipulates that deviations from the industry-wide arrangements are
only permissible if the deviation is favorable for the employee such that they
foresee higher wages or benefits, should be redefined to also include job
guarantees — even if these are given in exchange for concessions on pay.
Third, the straightjacket of the industry-wide wage contracts could be eased
further by lifting the Tarifbindung,
which still commits a company to the industry-wide agreement even if it has
cancelled its membership with the employers’ federation, and allowing companies
to negotiate individual wage deals with their workforces (and their trade union
representatives), effective immediately. Together, these measures would
ensure that the silent erosion of the industry-wide wage agreements, observed
over the last decade, gains more momentum.
In many
respects, the wage round in the metal industry, which is just getting under
way, could be seen as a bellwether for changes in the overly rigid labour
market institutions. Having suffered a major defeat in a conflict over
working hours in Eastern Germany this summer, unwavering IG Metall trade unionists are now demanding a
4% pay-rise for the 3.5 million workers in the sector from January
onwards. With the labour market still in the doldrums, metal workers are
unlikely to get much more than half of what they demanded, however, and will possibly
have to make concessions on working hours, too. The latter actually hints
at an interesting avenue to improve cost competitiveness. It seems that
companies find it easier to convince their workforce to put in longer hours
without being fully compensated for the additional time than to negotiate a pay
cut or a pay freeze. The path of least resistance has two branches:
raising the average work week or cutting holiday allowances. The public
sector, where finances are stretched to the limit, has already started to
introduce a longer work-week. Now the private sector needs to follow
suit.
To
contain the unrelenting upward pressure on non-wage labour costs, it will be
vital to keep pension and health-care contribution rates in check. To
this effect, a bipartisan healthcare reform passed last fall will likely result
in somewhat lower healthcare contribution rates (equally split between
employers and employees), through cutting medical expenses and introducing
patient fees. Now a pension reform is in the making, which aims at improving
the long-term sustainability of public finances by freezing pensions, raising
the retirement age and strengthening incentives for individual pension savings
through phasing in deferred taxation for such savings. As part of a
general overhaul of taxation, we also might see a major cutback of tax breaks
in exchange for a simpler tax system with lower income tax rates. While
such a tax overhaul would likely reduce the distortions caused by the present
tax system, it is unlikely to match the tax relief implemented by the Schroeder
government over the past few years. In fact, further consolidation on the
expenditure side is needed to ensure that the budget deficit eases back to 3%
of GDP in 2005.
Last but
not least, the political horse-trading between the regional states and the
federal government in the mediation process about implementing Chancellor
Schroeder’s reform agenda these last few months underscores the fact that Germany’s federal political system urgently
needs to be streamlined. In particular, the fiscal responsibilities of
the federal government have to be more clearly separated from those of the
regional states in order to prevent potential reform blockages in the
future. In addition, Germany is still lacking a national
stability pact that breaks the fiscal commitments under the Stability and
Growth Pact down into pledges for the different layers of government. In
preparation for a reform of the political system, a government-appointed commission
will report about reform proposals by mid-2004. Such a reform should
ensure that Germany’s decentralized political system,
which aside from the principle of representative voting is a cornerstone of its
post-war constitutional set-up, becomes fully functional again.
To sum
up, with GDP likely expanding at a 2.1% rate next year, Germany is clearly set to move up from the
bottom of the European growth league tables. But the remarks of the ‘soccer
philosopher’ Sepp Herberger half a century ago highlight that there is no time
for complacency — even after a victory much greater than the recent reform
compromise. After the reform is before the reform.
Important Disclosure Information at the end of this Forum
France: Push on Reforms and Privatisation
Eric Chaney (London)
This past year was the worst for France since 1993 from a growth and public
finances standpoint. I believe that growth has already resumed at the end of
2003 and that 2004 will be much more favourable for French companies and
workers than was 2003. Our 2.1% GDP growth forecast is still above the
consensus, and yet I think that risks are evenly balanced. On the one hand,
cyclical forces are, as always, probably more powerful than we are assuming; on
the other hand, the rise of the euro, if not checked, might choke the recovery
later in the year, when companies’ profits start to suffer. In this regard, I
would notice that the French economy is less sensitive to the euro exchange
rate than, for instance, Germany, because French exports are more oriented towards Europe. However, the themes that will
matter in 2004 are more likely to be political and structural ones, in my
view. Important midterm regional and European elections will take place in a
few months, which might either consolidate PM Raffarin’s government or, on the
contrary, trigger a cabinet reshuffle under another premier.
Whereas the public debate in France will
focus on political and sociological issues, such as how to help the Muslim community
integrate into French society and accept its secular laws, financial markets
will be more interested in seeing how the heavy lifting of the over-regulated
French economy undertaken by the government in 2003 will continue and bear
fruit for the corporate sector. Even though the proximity of midterm elections
is not propitious for ambitious reforms, I believe that, bumpy as the road might
be, reforms will go ahead on three tracks: reform of the healthcare system;
reform of wage negotiation rules, and privatisations.
Reforming the healthcare system — a top priority
With hindsight, the main reason behind
the spending overshoot in public finances last year was the uncontrolled
spiralling of medical and hospital spending. The particularity of the French
system is that most doctors are independent workers but, since patients are
reimbursed by the national healthcare fund, free access to doctors is
guaranteed and almost fully subsidised. Clearly, this system has become
over-generous and has generated a lot of excesses. The reform promised by the
government will embrace both hospitals and reimbursement rules. Since it will
be negotiated with unions and doctors, it will be even more difficult to push
through than the pension reform. I would expect significant breakthroughs only
after the elections. In the short term, the main task is the reduction of
public deficits in 2005. In the medium run, it is the reduction of the tax
burden and the cost of labour, since a part of healthcare costs is still financed
by payroll taxes.
Reforming wage-setting rules — a
discrete but ambitious reform
At the end of 2003, Minister of Social
Affairs Francois Fillon unveiled a very ambitious project that would radically
change the relationship between employees and employers. In a nutshell, M.
Fillon has proposed to decentralise and make more flexible the current system
by allowing companies to have direct negotiations with their workers, instead
of complying with branch agreements. Not surprisingly, unions rejected the
idea. More curiously, employers did not seem interested either. My impression
is that M. Fillon has carefully thought out his plans and wants to capitalise
on the success of the pension reform last year. Knowing that healthcare reform
will be the most difficult part of the government’s agenda, he will probably be
keen on succeeding on labour markets. At stake is nothing less than the
employment performance of France, which, after having been artificially boosted by the unfortunate 35-hour
regulation, has been quite disappointing over the last two years.
Privatisation — the safest way to increase flexibility and cut debt
Because deficits have soared in 2002 and
2003 and have accelerated the rise of the public debt, the government will be interested
in accelerating its privatisation program. Francis Mer’s track record has been
good so far: The Treasury took markets by surprise on several occasions. I
believe that this year we will see the beginning of much larger privatisation
operations concerning large public utilities. In reality, the government has
almost no choice, given the poor state of public finances and the commitment to
open domestic energy and postal markets. If, as our equity strategists
believe, European stock markets are well oriented in the first half of the
year, be prepared for other surprises.
Important Disclosure Information at the end of this Forum
Italy: Job Miracle Should Continue into 2004
Vincenzo Guzzo/Anna Maria Grimaldi (London)
The
year ahead will have several challenges for the Italian economy. Some of them will be in common with the
rest of the Euro area; others will be more specific to Corporate Italy. Will the upswing be sustainable and turn
into a phase of mature expansion? Or will a super-Euro dent the competitiveness of export-led
businesses? Will uncoordinated
fiscal and monetary policies derail the recovery train? At home, will PM Berlusconi manage to
keep the many voices of his coalition in tune? Or will the
wave of social unrest that is opposing pension reform open new cracks within
the government coalition?
Notwithstanding the importance of all these issues, we concentrate on
one topic: the unexpectedly strong performance of the labor market and, in
particular, its prospects looking forward.
Impressive numbers
According
to data from the quarterly labor survey, nearly two million jobs were created between January 1999 and July 2003. That is almost 10% of total employment
in a matter of three and half years.
The annual employment growth rate, which peaked at 3.2% in early 2001,
was still running at a very decent 1.1% during the first three quarters of this
year. Over the same period, the
unemployment rate dropped all the way down from a ridge of 11.9% to the current
8.8%, the lowest rate since National Statistics ISTAT started conducting the
survey in 1993. Numbers from
quarterly national accounts show a similar, although somewhat smoother,
profile.
The extra boost came from South
From
a geographical standpoint, the improvement kicked in the wealthy Northern and
Central regions as early as 1995-6, on the back of the powerful cyclical
upswing that followed the last period currency of devaluation and then extended
well into the following years, despite the anemic underlying economic
performance. But
the extra boost that turned a gradual improvement into a real ‘job
miracle’ from 1999 onward came from the South, the area where the unemployment
rate is highest. Progress has
petered out in the North, where the unemployment rate, at 3.8%, has probably
reached, and possibly exceeded, its natural limits, we believe, but continues
relentlessly in southern Italy.
Flexibility: yes, but…
“Flexibilization”
has played a role. In response to
legislation that made the use of part-time and temporary positions easier,
firms have relied more significantly on these flexible jobs. According to national account data, the
share of part-time over total employees moved from 5.2% in 1999 to 6.3% during
the first half of this year, while the share of temporary positions moved from
9.5% to 9.8%. Yet, these statistics
are still quite unimpressive when compared to the average Euroland
numbers. Data from the OECD Labor
Force Statistics show that the share of temp jobs,
although declining due to cyclical factors, is still nearly 13% on the
continent. Even bigger is the gap
in terms of part-time positions that, in Euroland, exceeds 16% of total
employees, a share almost three times as large as the Italian one.
…bonus on new hires is the key factor
In
fact, about one million jobs added to the economy since 1999 are traditional
permanent full-time positions. How
could that happen during a period of major economic deceleration? Firing rigidities may justify some
resilience during downturns, but certainly fall short of explaining such
progress. More likely, we think,
tax breaks for new hires introduced with the 2001 budget are the major factor
behind the rise in permanent jobs.
These incentives were temporarily suspended in
2002 in an effort to contain the budget deficit within the 3% Maastricht threshold, but they have been
reintroduced this year and extended through 2006.
Too good to be true
Among
all these numbers, there is a productivity puzzle though. Throughout the 1999-2003 period, GDP growth barely averaged a meager 1.5%, two-tenths
short of the 1.7% employment growth rate recorded over the same interval,
leaving marginal labor productivity rates in negative territory. A larger share of flexible positions,
which normally coincide with lower-skilled workers, may have done the trick,
but the mild rise in these jobs, as shown above, cannot be the main culprit. We prefer to think that a shrinking
underground economy, which in 1998 was estimated as
27.8% of GDP, is behind the puzzle.
While, to our knowledge, no recent estimates are
available on the evolution of these figures, such a large ‘shadow
economy,’ together with a low participation rate (still below 62% for the
entire population and 56% among women) and the southern bias in the recent
progress, are all compelling evidence of the role that these incentives have
played and could keep playing in the future. Add some cyclical upswing and the impact
of the new Biagi reform and there are ingredients for
further impressive gains in the year ahead. But don’t
complain about weak productivity.
All these new hires have now appeared in statisticians’
books, but who knows for how long they were already there.
Important Disclosure Information at the end of this Forum
Spain: Living on Hot Building
Anna Grimaldi & Vincenzo Guzzo (London)
Still the growth
stalwart
The Spanish economy has remained the European growth
stalwart in 2003, and we expect it to continue to outperform its European
neighbors well into 2004. In an
adverse global environment, strong economic growth could only come from
domestic sources. Income tax cuts and healthy job creation supported household
spending, while negative real interest rates continued to boost construction
spending. In 2004, we look for
these trends to remain in place. Household consumption should stabilize as job
creation gains further momentum and construction investment should slow
marginally, as we envisage only a gradual increase in interest rates. Finally,
with a general election scheduled for early 2004, some further boost to the
economy should come from government consumption. While we remain bullish on the
Spanish economy, we think that the housing and the construction sector demand
close monitoring
But what about buoyant house prices?
Spanish house prices were up almost 120% in nominal terms
between 1990 and 2002. In 2002, prices were 85% higher than in 1995 and a large
part of the increase occurred between 2000 and 2002, when prices rose 16% a
year, by far the highest observed in the Eurozone and
even higher than in the UK.
Recent figures from the European Mortgage Federation suggest that in
early 2003 there were no signs of moderation and, if
anything, house prices accelerated further, rising at above 17% compared to a
year earlier. Given that real
estate is the main household asset, changes in house prices might have
important implications for households investment
decisions and financial positions.
Macro econometric estimates from the Bank of Spain suggest that real
house prices are roughly 10% overvalued compared to a long-term fair value. The issue here is whether this pace of
increase in house prices is sustainable and, if not, what could trigger a
trend-inversion? Sustainability
depends on trends in house prices determinants over the coming years, we
believe.
The dynamism of Spanish house prices in the second half of
the nineties is likely the result of an excess of demand, fuelled partly by
demographics changes, strong employment growth, and mainly by the large decline
in the cost of mortgage lending. Interest
rate on house mortgages fell from just above 10% in early 1996 to 3.4% in
October of this year. Income tax
breaks on mortgage financing have also encouraged households to take on more
debt. As a
result, household indebtedness rose from 43% in 1996 to 67% of GDP in the first
quarter of 2003 and is now 10% higher than the Eurozone
average (58%). Mortgage
lending as a percentage of GDP rose from 30% in 2000 to almost 40% of GDP in
September of this year while it remained stable in the Eurozone
Demand to remain
strong but supply is catching up
Demand for new houses rose quickly during the 90s fuelled by
a 20% increase in people between 24-39 years (the first-time buyer age
bracket), a rising proportion of single households (due to a higher divorce
rate and people leaving home earlier), and strong immigration flows (around 1.2
million). These trends should remain in place over the next five years,
supporting demand for housing and hence prices. We estimate that demand for new houses
should average roughly 400,000 as the number of single households rises further
and immigration flows are sustained (estimated at
175,000). During the 90s, supply of
new houses has been lagging demand partly due to the constraints arising from
the Ley del Suelo,
which creates a significant lag between applying for planning permission and
receiving the approval. However,
housing starts skyrocketed in the last two years, reaching a peak of 640,000 in
2003. The increase in supply should
contribute to a gradual moderation in the pace of increase house prices.
Interest rates are on
the rise…
In a rising interest rate environment, the responsiveness of
house prices and consumption to changes in nominal rates becomes a key element
to assess macro risks for the economy.
The sensitivity of housing consumption to changes in interest rates is known to be much higher if mortgage lending is at
variable rather than fixed rates, and this is indeed the case for the Spanish
economy. Roughly, all mortgage lending is at short-term rate, adjusted every 12
months, as opposed to the majority of other European countries where house
financing is at fixed long-term rates.
What matters is the affordability of mortgages as interest rates rise. The European Mortgage Federation
shows that a 100 basis points change in interest rates translates into a 20 bp increase/fall in mortgage lending rates in the same
quarter and is fully passed through the next
year. The impact of a change in
interest rates on mortgage payment is estimated to
have been negligible on the ratio of interest payments to GDP. As we only envisage a 175 basis points
increase in the ECB refinancing rate over the next two years, the impact on
household finances and house prices should be limited. A 50 basis point increase in interest
rates will nevertheless have a significant impact on first-time buyers, who
generally borrow between 75% and 80% of the value of the property and for whom
the BBVA estimates affordability) to be close to 50% already in 2003. First-time buyers have a crucial role in
the Spanish housing market has they buy at the bottom of the property ladder,
allowing home owners to trade up and thus driving demand all the way up.
…but the impact
should be limited for now
While the recent trend in Spanish house prices does not look
sustainable in the medium term, we do not expect to see a sharp correction in
the next year as the dynamics of supply and demand remain favourable
and interest rate should rise only gradually. That said the later the inversion
in the observed trend occurs, the sharper the adjustment and the larger the
impact on the economy.
Important Disclosure Information at the end of this Forum
Netherlands: Turning the Corner?
Annemarieke Christian (London)
After recording its sharpest slowdown in
around 20 years, the Dutch economy should finally turn a corner in 2004.
Following average annual GDP growth rates of 3.6% in the second half of the
1990s, the economy came to a virtual standstill in 2002, before likely
recording its first annual contraction in two decades in 2003. Having
fallen into recession territory at the end of 2002, the economy finally inched
back into positive territory in the fall of 2003. We think the economy should
pick up modestly going into 2004. The wage freeze for 2004 and 2005 agreed by
the social partners should help to bring the much needed turnaround in
cost-competitiveness and corporate profits, though substantive austerity
measures by the government will continue to weigh on the economy. Growth
will likely still remain well below trend, at 0.9% on our forecasts, thus
continuing to fall well short of the euro area average, which we see growing by
2% next year.
We still see a number of factors dragging
on the economy in 2004, in particular substantial fiscal tightening from the
government and likely further increases in pension contributions. Despite
substantive austerity measures implemented in 2003, the budget deficit is
likely to have come very close to the 3% Maastricht limit. The government has planned further drastic measures
(amounting to around 1.8% of GDP) for 2004. Though the Central Planning
Bureau has now estimated that the budget deficit could breach the 3% limit in
2004, we don’t think the government is likely to implement additional austerity
measures. The Dutch government has two options within the Maastricht framework to avoid the
excessive deficit procedure being started, without the necessity of additional
austerity measures (see European Economics Comment: Netherlands: Deficit Estimated to Breach 3% Limit in 2004, December 4, 2003). Next to that, consumers and
employers are likely to see further hikes in contributions rates by pension
funds. Pension funds are still in the process of restoring their coverage
ratios, which were hit in the equity market slowdown of previous years.
The Dutch economy is emerging from its
worst recession in two decades as we write. After already dipping into the red
sporadically from 2001, the economy moved deep into recession territory at the
end of 2002, contracting by a cumulated 1.2% up to the middle of 2003. But
after being on a steady downtrend since the end of 1999, Dutch GDP growth finally
seems to have found a bottom now. For 2003 as a whole, the economy likely
shrunk by 0.7% and the output gap widened to 3.8 percent on our estimates. The
output gap is set to widen further in 2004 to levels last seen in the recession
of the early 1980s, as growth likely still remains well below trend next year.
With GDP growth not likely to return to the buoyant levels of the late 1990s,
it will take a number of years for the output gap to close completely. We have
previously noted that the marked widening of the output gap in the Netherlands points to a sharp fall in
inflation over the next few years (see Dutch Economics: Deflation – Who’s
Next? August 5, 2003). The
wage agreement for 2004 and 2005 will likely add to the deflationary pressures.
The Netherlands have laid the foundation for a turnaround in the economy with the
recent agreement between the social partners to freeze contractual wages in
2004 and to keep contractual wage growth close to zero in 2005. This
tackles one of the main culprits of the economic downturn over the last few
years, namely the marked loss of competitiveness which was largely caused by
the surge in unit labour cost growth from 1999. A tight labour market led
to excessive wage growth in the latter part of the 1990s. In combination with
dropping productivity growth, as companies held on to their workers into the
downturn due to previous difficulties in hiring workers in the tight labour
market, unit labour costs shot up.
Similar to the economic situation in the
early 1980s, the Netherlands
are returning to a policy of wage moderation in order to bring the economy out
of a deep recession. In the ‘Wassenaar agreement’ of November 1982, the
social partners agreed on moderate wage growth. Back then, the Dutch economy
posted two consecutive annual contractions. As a result of the moderate-wage-growth
strategy pursued after the ‘Wassenaar agreement’, the growth rate of
compensation per employee plunged from 6% in 1982 to 0.5% in 1984. Over the
same period, unit labour cost growth for the total economy fell from 4.2% in
1982 to -2.8% in 1984. On the back of the accompanying recovery in employment
growth, the economy returned to average GDP growth rates of just over 3% in the
second half of the 1980s.
This time around, the social partners
have agreed on a wage freeze for 2004 and ‘close to zero’ wage growth in 2005.
As some wage contracts for 2004 had already been negotiated before the
agreement, the moderation in compensation per employee is likely to be more
pronounced in 2005. This moderation in wage growth should bring excessive unit
labour cost growth down markedly in the next few year. Wage moderation will
affect two key components of the economic recovery, namely the price
competitiveness of exports and corporate profits. Regarding the first factor,
the Central Planning Bureau, a government sponsored think tank, estimates that
the prices of domestically produced goods have outpaced the relevant world
trade price by a cumulated 8.5% since 2001. Similarly, corporate profits were
hit markedly by excessive unit labour cost growth. Profit margins (the ratio
between output prices, measured by the GDP deflator, and input prices, measured
by unit labour costs) have contracted over the last three years. A marked
easing in unit labour cost growth is key to turning around these factors, which
have been weighing on the Dutch economy over the last few years.
So while the wage freeze is a key factor
in the recovery of the Dutch economy next year, a number of other factors
weighing on the economy should keep GDP growth below trend. Our view of a
continued underperformance of the Dutch economy is supported by business survey
evidence so far, which still shows a marked underperformance of the Netherlands compared to the remainder of
the euro area. Our coincident survey indicator, which takes into account
information on output expectations, current output, inventories and demand,
still lies well below the euro area indicator. This supports our view that the
recovery in the Dutch economy is likely to be much more subdued than in the
remainder of the euro area. But after all the gloomy titles to our notes on the
Dutch economy over the last few years, we are looking forward to some slightly
more upbeat news in the new year. The fallen angel finally seems to be rising
from the ashes!
Important Disclosure Information at the end of this Forum
Belgium: Rejoining the Pack
Annemarieke Christian (London)
After
outperforming many of its euro area peers on the growth front in 2003, the
Belgian economy is likely to rejoin the pack again in 2004, growing in line
with the euro area average. But this would see the
economy returning back to trend in 2004, after three years well below
potential. On the fiscal front, Belgium has also been one of the more
prudent governments in the last few years. The government budget balance may
even have remained in surplus for a fourth consecutive year in 2003. However,
as we explain below, this is largely due to one-off revenues related to a
payment received for the takeover of a pension fund from a state-owned company.
Whether these revenues will indeed enter the calculation of the budget balance
is still in the hands of Eurostat, the Statistics
Office of the European Commission. Therefore the starting point for the 2004 budget balance
remains unclear. However, it is likely to record a deficit whether the pension
fund revenues are counted or not.
Belgium was one of the few countries
in the euro area to record an acceleration in GDP
growth in 2003. Next to cuts in both income and corporate tax rates, the
two-year wage agreement reached at the beginning of the year helped domestic
demand to recover. This more than offset
the drag from weak global trade on the export-oriented Belgian economy. As a
result, Belgium outperformed the euro area by
a half point in terms of GDP growth. In
2004, the economy should be able to tap into the global trade recovery again.
Next to that, the moderating effects of the wage agreement should continue to
boost the economy. In addition, the government is planning cuts in non-wage labour costs of around 0.2% of GDP. These factors should
give further support to the recovery in domestic demand that kicked off in
2003. We think this boost from both external and domestic demand should bring
GDP growth up to 2.0% in 2004, from the 1.1% likely recorded in 2003.
On
the fiscal front, the Belgian government could be helped
by a payment relating to the takeover of a pension fund. The government is
assuming responsibility for the liabilities of the Belgacom
pension fund. The pension scheme was a
funded scheme with dedicated assets.
Instead of transferring the funded scheme, the assets were
liquidated and paid to the government in cash. As the assets do not fully cover the future
liabilities, which the government has estimated at ˆ5 billion, Belgacom will likely make an additional transfer of cash to
cover the difference. The transfer of the cash relating to the assets
(amounting to around ˆ3.5-3.7 billion, or 1.3–1.4% of GDP) would enter the
calculation of the 2003 balance.
Meanwhile, the cash relating to the additional shortfall (around ˆ1.4
billion or 0.5% of GDP) will likely be booked in the 2004 budget, if accepted
by Eurostat.
Without these extra revenues we estimate that
the Belgian budget balance would move from a slight 0.1% of GDP surplus in 2002
to a 1.2% of GDP deficit in 2003. With
the economy likely to pick up markedly next year, we would then expect the
deficit to shrink slightly to 1.0% of GDP in 2004. If the government is
allowed to take the payments from Belgacom
into account, the budget balance could post a slight surplus again this
year. In 2004, the budget would then
likely move back into the red, with a deficit of 0.5% of GDP, on our estimates.
However, first indications from Eurostat suggest that
they are reluctant to take the payment into account
for the calculation of the budget balance. A final decision from Eurostat is expected in early 2004.
The
impact of the payment on debt dynamics is also still unclear. The payment is to
be transferred to the ‘Zilverfonds,’
a fund set up by the government to be used to meet the future costs of the
aging population. According to the
Belgian government, funds accumulated in the Zilverfonds,
which are invested in government bonds, are classed as
debt reduction under the European accounting rules. Together with favourable
debt dynamics, we estimate that the ˆ5 billion payment could bring the Belgian
debt level down from 105.8% in 2002 to around 103% of GDP in 2003 and possibly
even below the 100% mark in 2004. While
these one-off payments would help to bring the excessive Belgian debt level
down faster toward the 60% Maastricht limit, with favourable
effects on interest payments, we think the government should rather focus on
structural measures to bring its budget into balance and its debt level down.
With
the economic developments in Belgium largely in line with those seen in the rest of the euro area, fiscal policy and the accounting
issues related to it might in fact turn out to be the most striking feature of
the Belgian economy in 2004.
Important Disclosure Information at the end of this Forum
Sweden: Introspection
Elga Bartsch (London)
For
the Swedish economy the few last years were very much dominated by
international factors, such as the new economy boom and bust and the question
as to whether Sweden should or should not join
EMU. In the coming year, the themes for the Swedish economy will likely
refocus on domestic issues. Here, a convergence of GDP growth
with the rest of Europe could lead to a re-assessment of the relative growth
potential of the largest Nordic economy, we believe.
After
an impressive outperformance of the Swedish economy vis-à-vis the euro area of
a cumulated 2.5 percentage points over the last two years, GDP growth rates
between the two regions are likely to converge again. Our Swedish 2004
growth forecast for 2.5% GDP growth is only slightly higher than the non-workday
adjusted Euroland forecast of 2.2% (see Eric Chaney and Joachim Fels’s
comment elsewhere on these pages). Compared with an average growth rate
of 0.5% in the euro area and of 1.5% in Sweden during 2003, this implies a
more moderate recovery in Sweden than the one we foresee in
continental Europe. A large part of this divergence is due to the consumer
cycle. Whereas consumer spending in the euro area is likely to be
propelled by a combination of pent-up demand, income tax cuts, normalizing
inflation perceptions, and a robust job market, Sweden has seen a large part of the
consumer story already over the last two years, thanks to substantial income
tax reductions and interest rates cuts. The Swedish recovery will rely to
a larger extent on export demand and investment spending.
Against
the background of a headline GDP growth rate that probably won’t be too
dissimilar from that of the euro area next year, will come as a timely reminder
that the same actually holds for potential output growth. Most forecasters
would put the potential growth rate — i.e., the growth rate that is
sustainable in the long-run — at around 2.25% for Sweden and slightly below that for
the euro economy. This implies that in contrast to the euro economy,
there isn’t a lot of spare capacity in the Swedish economy at the
moment. For me, this — together with potential upside surprises on
growth outside Sweden — is the main reason
why the Riksbank will likely be reluctant to cut interest rates again.
Instead I see the Bank being on hold well into next year before eventually
starting to embark on a gradual tightening campaign, nudging interest rates
toward a more neutral level. That said, the minutes of the
Riksbank’s executive board meeting in December, which showed a slim 4
to 2
majority in favour of steady rates, highlights that the call for an unchanged
repo rate of 2.75% has become a close one. But in my mind it would be a
mistake for the Riksbank to give in to the pressure created by repeated calls
for lower rates from both government politicians and trade unions.
In
gauging the likelihood of a Riksbank rate cut in early 2004, we will need to
keep a close eye on the incoming activity and inflation data,
as well as the currency and the weather reports. While the former will be
influencing import price developments, the latter will be determining the
electricity price trajectory this winter. Base-effects from last
year’s electricity price explosion could push UND1X inflation to less
than 1% — the Riksbank’s lower tolerance level — in early
2004. Yet, the Bank is likely to look through these energy-related
gyrations in inflation and has in fact started to emphasize UND1X excl. energy
recently. Instead the Bank will pay more attention, we think, to the
upcoming multi-year wage round to gauge potential inflationary pressures
emanating from labour costs in the medium run. We therefore believe that
the short end of the Swedish market is getting a bit ahead of itself on hopes
for another Riksbank rate cut — especially now that currency seems to be
trading down again. At the same time, the long end of the Swedish bond market
seems to be fairly valued against 10-year German Bund yields. If anything, the
Bank could remain on hold for longer than our present forecast, which pencils
in a first 25 bp rate hike in the second quarter, indicates.
Recognising
that the potential growth rate of the Swedish economy seems to be relatively
low compared with the average growth rate recorded over the last five years,
the government headed by Prime Minister Persson is planning to embark on a
pro-growth initiative in 2004. A key event in putting together a reform
agenda will be marked by a Social Democratic party conference in early April,
where new recipes to revive growth on a sustainable basis will be
presented. In this context, a proposal to significantly reduce, if not
totally abolish, the wealth tax is likely to make headlines in the financial
press. This proposal could already be included in the Spring Budget Bill
and as such could turn out to be a trigger for renewed SEK strengthening.
Our currency team sees the SEK strengthening against the euro toward 8.70 by
mid-year, from 9.07 today. That said, we believe
that a lower wealth tax is primarily a token gesture. Just check with you
millionaire friends in Stockholm, and you will find that hardly
anyone actually pays wealth-tax.
Important Disclosure Information at the end of this Forum
Emerging Europe: A Positive Growth Scenario
Riccardo Barbieri (London)
Our
macroeconomic prognosis for the region is favourable.
With the exception of Russia,
which should nevertheless maintain a solid performance, we expect economic
growth in EMEA to accelerate over the next two years. Inflation should continue to trend down,
largely because we expect Russia
and Turkey to make further progress in reducing inflation, probably achieving
single-digit rates in 2005.
Current account and fiscal positions manageable.
Current account positions will probably
continue to differ quite significantly across the region, but we expect that
both central Europe and Turkey will benefit from recovery in the European economy. Budget positions should either improve
or stabilise in 2005 after worsening moderately in 2004. We expect the improvement in fiscal
performance to be due mostly to favourable cyclical conditions.
US dollar likely to weaken further.
The significant appreciation of the euro
against the dollar has been a key factor supporting disinflation in Turkey
and South Africa and allowing the central European currencies to regain
competitiveness without importing too much inflation via their exchange rate to
the dollar. The projections of our currency
team suggest that this will remain an important factor in 2004 and 2005, as the
dollar keeps weakening against the euro and the yen. However, they expect the extent of the
dollar’s fall to be smaller than in 2002 and 2003. We see some additional margin for the
central European currencies and the Turkish lira to weaken against the euro
(gaining competitiveness in their main export markets) while remaining stable
or perhaps even rising vis-à-vis the dollar. This is also a key factor in forecasting
the paths of the rouble and the rand in 2004 and 2005.
Oil price outlook favourable, especially for Russia.
With Brent oil trading above US$30/bl,
energy prices are higher than expected
earlier in the year, and most forecasters now believe elevated oil prices could be maintained at least
through 2004. Prices should remain
high enough to boost growth in Russia
and other oil-producing countries, but not too high to stifle growth and boost
inflation in oil-importing countries (especially considering the weakness of
the dollar).
Russia: only
a moderate deceleration in 2005.
Real GDP growth
slowed from a peak of 7.1% in 2Q03 to 6.2% in 3Q03. The latest data, however, suggest that
industrial production and business confidence have moved up slightly in 4Q03. As a result, we have raised our estimate
for 2003 from 6.2% to 6.6%. Largely
because of growth in the energy sector, we expect that next year the economy at
large will expand by less than in 2003.
Still, our new 5.5% 2004 real GDP growth forecast
is significantly higher than our previous estimate of 4.6%. We do not expect the Yukos affair to
derail Russia’s economic recovery and the reform plans of the Putin
administration. For 2005, we have
tentatively pencilled in a 4.5% real GDP growth rate to reflect both the risk
that oil prices may ease somewhat and our Oil & Gas team’s
expectation that production growth will slow further to around 5%.
European recovery and exchange rate
competitiveness should support growth in central Europe.
We think the main
drivers of growth dynamics will be the EU recovery, changes in exchange rates
and pressure to correct recently over-loose fiscal policies. The Czech Republic and Hungary are most exposed to the Euroland
recovery. In each, domestic demand
is likely to slow in 2004 as indirect tax rates are raised and higher inflation
lowers real household income. But, as
the 2006 elections approach, with both governments facing difficult election
campaigns, we expect the pace of fiscal tightening to slow, particularly in Hungary.
While Poland is slightly less exposed to global growth, the zloty is increasingly
competitive, and parliamentary and presidential elections in 2005 argue for
little fiscal tightening in the short term. Oliver Weeks expects a new government to
begin tightening only late in 2005, and real GDP growth to remain among the
strongest in the region, at around 4.8% in 2005.
Strong
growth and continuing disinflation expected in Turkey.
Serhan Cevik is quite optimistic on the
outlook for the next two years, forecasting 5.5% real growth in 2004 and 6.4%
in 2005. In his view, continuing
productivity gains should hold down unit labour costs. Owing to a pick-up in global trade and
in European imports, this should lead to increases in Turkish exports of 10.5%
next year and 11.4% in 2005.
However, the leading engine of Turkey’s
growth in the next two years will be final domestic demand, in our view. Despite continuing fiscal austerity,
Serhan foresees a gradual recovery in consumer spending, up 5.2% in 2004 and
6.0% in 2005, following a 4.8% rise this year. He also believes that improving
corporate profit margins, rising productivity and the declining cost of funding
should lead to a sharp increase in business investment. Core price indices show no underlying
inflation build-up, and the gradual recovery in domestic demand should not
disturb the disinflation trend.
South Africa: recovery
under way, as domestic demand stays strong.
Economic growth this
year has slowed down markedly, to
around 2%, from 3.6% in 2002. We
estimate that the 4Q02/4Q03 increase in real GDP will be an even lower
1.3%. The main cause for the
slowdown has been a sharp worsening in the net trade position on the back of
the rand’s appreciation.
Looking forward, the 550 basis points of cumulative interest rate reduction
engineered by the Reserve Bank since June, the stimulative stance of fiscal
policy, and the beneficial effect of lower inflation on real disposable income,
will probably keep domestic final demand strong. With export markets recovering and some
contribution from inventories, we expect growth to accelerate in 2004 to an
average of 2.8%. 2005 will probably see stronger growth, and slightly higher
inflation. Based on our expectation
that the rand will depreciate in
2H04, we expect average real GDP growth to accelerate further in 2005, to
3.7%. Coming months will probably
see a further decline in year-on-year CPIX inflation to a low of 3.8% in
January and then a moderate increase over the course of 2004, due in part to
base effects. We expect CPIX inflation
to remain within the 3-6% target range in 2005, but hovering close to the upper
limit of that band. Against this
backdrop, we expect a moderate tightening in monetary policy commencing in
2H04.
Important Disclosure Information at the end of this Forum
South Africa: Stronger Growth, Rand Permitting
Riccardo Barbieri (London)
2003 will likely be remembered as
a year of considerable achievements for South
Africa in terms of
macroeconomic stability, particularly in terms of declining inflation and
interest rates. A year ago, the
inflation rate measured by the CPIX, the index of consumer prices excluding
mortgages, stood at 10.8% year-on-year, and the CPI inflation rate was 12.5%. We estimate that 2003 will end with a 4.1%
CPIX inflation rate (unchanged from November) and a zero CPI inflation
rate. In line with this improvement,
interest rates have fallen sharply, with the repo rate of the South African
Reserve Bank (SARB) falling by a total of 550 basis points. This was all made possible by a strong
recovery in the rand exchange rate, which, similarly to 2002, exceeded even the
most optimistic expectations.
The other side of the coin is
that South Africa’s
economic and employment growth performance has been rather disappointing this
year. We estimate that 2003 will close
with a 1.9% average real GDP growth rate and a meagre 4Q/4Q growth of
1.3%. Even assuming that the official
figures are later revised up, we do not think that the estimated growth rate
will significantly exceed 2%. Meanwhile,
according to official statistics, non-agricultural private-sector employment
contracted by 0.6% in the first quarter, and the overall unemployment rate rose
to 31.2% in March, from an average of 30.0% in 2002. Given that the economy slowed down further in
the second quarter before slowly recovering in the second half of the year, the
annual unemployment rate will be probably higher than in the first quarter.
Against this backdrop, the
official projections of the South African National Treasury are for a
significant acceleration in economy growth in 2004–06, and a return to jobs
creation. The Treasury’s latest
projections call for a real GDP growth rate of 3.3% in 2004, 3.7% in 2005, and
4.0% in 2006. With fiscal policy much more
stimulative than in recent years and easier monetary policy, we believe the
policy mix is the right one to deliver stronger growth. The improvement in the global economy adds
credence to the Treasury’s projections.
Our own prognosis for 2004 is less positive than the Treasury’s,
although this week we raised our real GDP growth forecast to 2.8%. On the other hand, we concur with the
Treasury’s view on 2005 growth.
The key issue, though, is whether the rand exchange
rate will weaken enough to allow the traded sector of the economy to return to
a healthy growth rate. While this will
depend in part on domestic developments, the most critical factor will be the
trend in world commodity prices (notably metals), not only because of their
importance in South Africa’s output and exports, but perhaps more importantly
because such prices represent the key factor determining how international
model-driven investors trade this currency.
Our macroeconomic projections are heavily influenced by our expectation
that the Bull Run in metals prices will run out of steam
over the course of next year, and this will allow the South African policy
authorities to engineer a soft landing of the rand exchange rate. If that failed to happen, though, we would
expect a significantly worse economic performance in the next two years than
suggested even by our own forecasts, particularly in 2005.
As mentioned above, this week we
raised our 2004 real GDP forecast from 2.5% to 2.8%, and announced a new 2005
forecast of 3.7%. The main reasons for
the upward revision to the 2004 estimates are that the latest demand-side
national accounts data showed stronger domestic final demand than we
anticipated, and there were upward revisions to the back data. We feel that this strength is sustainable,
given the sharp decline in bank lending rates and continuing fiscal
stimulus. (Government spending should
rise further as a share of GDP in the 2004/05 fiscal year, before levelling off in
2005/06.) In addition, there has been an
encouraging improvement in business confidence in 4Q03. This leads us to believe that gross fixed
investment will continue to grow in coming quarters, albeit at a slower rate
than in the days of the weak rand.
The worsening in South Africa’s net foreign trade should
also diminish, as the world economy recovers, thus creating better export
opportunities for South African firms. Going into 2H04, we expect these factors to be
compounded by a weaker rand (see below).
Our 2004 real GDP forecast would be even more optimistic if we assumed a
larger contribution from stock building and, on the supply side, a very strong
rebound in agricultural production after this year’s drop. For 2005, our positive view on South African
growth stems from our expectation that, in addition to continuing strength in
domestic demand, the economy will also benefit in full from a more competitive
exchange rate while interest rates rise only moderately.
We have also upped our rand
forecast. The weakening of the rand against the US
dollar over the past few days could signal a turning point for this currency
(similar to what happened in the opposite direction at the end of 2001). However, we expect that the rand’s correlation with metals prices (see Exhibit 1,
which is based on computations by our colleague V.R. Chandramouli) will
reassert itself in 1Q04. We expect the
rand/dollar exchange rate to test the 6.0 level once again in 1Q04. In the absence of unforeseen domestic
problems or policy mistakes (which have become rather unlikely, in our view),
the rand will probably stay strong until the current rally (or, should we say,
bubble?) in metals prices comes to an end.
We believe that the key factors that could bring about
such turn-around are the slowdown in Chinese growth expected by our Asian colleagues
and the beginning of a policy tightening by the US Federal Reserve, which our
US economists believe will occur in 3Q04.
We also continue to think that the South African authorities will be
more inclined to accommodate or promote a gentle weakening of the rand after
the general elections (in April) and key wage negotiations (in May and June)
are out of the way. Changes to our
forecasts are particularly significant with respect to the next two quarters,
as we expect the rand (currently at 6.60 against the dollar) to strengthen to
6.5 at the end of March and weaken to 7.0 at the end of June. Our previous March and June forecasts were
7.0 and 7.5, respectively.
South African interest rates are
close to the cyclical bottom, in our view.
The South
African Reserve Bank (SARB) surprised us on the downside, by cutting its policy
rate by only 50 basis points on December 11 (although we agree completely with
the move from a normative point of view).
Given our bullish near-term rand scenario and positive expectations for
inflation in the coming months, it makes sense to us to expect one last 50
basis-point cut at the February meeting.
After that, we believe the SARB will be on hold until the 4Q04. At that stage, with the rand moving to 7.8 by
end-September and both current and projected CPIX inflation rising above 5%
(and perhaps even closer to the upper limit of the 3–6% inflation target
range), on our forecasts, we would expect the SARB to hike its policy rate by
100 basis points. This would be
followed, in our view, by a further 50 basis points of tightening in 1Q05. Alternative rand scenarios from the one we
have outlined would obviously lead to significantly different interest-rate
decisions by the SARB. South Africa will
no doubt remain a very interesting economy to watch.
Important Disclosure Information at the end of this Forum
Japan: The Year of Truth
Robert Alan Feldman (Tokyo)
Japan faces a year of truth in 2004. A
positive outlook for financial markets requires faster reforms and more
restructuring. I believe that both will occur.
Macro
Reforms Move Faster
The
political stars are aligned for faster reform, in my view. First, political
power struggles are over. On the right, PM Koizumi has won a new three-year
term as LDP party head, and the recent general election eliminated a number of
anti-reform members from the party. On the left, the far-left splinter parties
were devastated in the general election, leaving the center-left Democratic
Party of Japan as the dominant voice of the opposition. Second, in the general
election, the voters demanded change. With an Upper House election coming next
July, both parties must focus on policy.
The
pension issue is most pressing, and much progress has occurred. The LDP has
decided to push payouts as low as 50% of income (compared to more than 59%
now), and to cap contributions at about 18 1/2% of wages (compared to 13 1/2%
now). This result reversed a high-tax, high-spend proposal from bureaucrats,
and thus bodes well for other fiscal reforms.
Financial
sector reform remains difficult. The recent failure of a large regional bank
showed that the authorities have teeth. However, many more financial sector
problems remain, e.g., how to treat deferred tax assets, how to improve loan
classification, how to raise bank profitability, and how to avoid a credit
crunch. Moreover, I believe financial system reform is doomed to fail without
progress in shrinking government lenders.
Spending
policies carry similar challenges. Even huge cuts of public works would not
suffice to restore fiscal soundness, because public works comprise only about
one-quarter of general government spending. Large cuts of current spending are
crucial. Pensions are one part, but healthcare (especially for the elderly) and
unemployment insurance also demand attention. FY04 budget decisions will be
finalized in February-March, and will have many clues on the speed of reform.
Tax
reform, which had stalled over the last two years, may now accelerate. The
LDP’s Tax Committee saw major personnel changes when some anti-reform members
lost their seats in the recent general election.
Privatization
will also be high on the agenda, particularly that of the Japan Highway
Corporation. Further Postal Savings reform will be debated through the year.
But privatization will not end with these two trophy cases. The difficult
fiscal situation argues for aggressive asset sales.
Deregulation
is less eye-catching, but just as vital. Action on special economic zones must
accelerate, and ministries must cooperate more with the PM’s wishes. Such
cooperation is more likely now that the anti-reform head of a major public
enterprise has been fired.
Corporate
Reform: Asset Reallocation Proceeds
While
policy makers push macro reform, management pushes micro reform. Already,
recurring profits are higher as a share of GDP than the average level of the
past 20 years. Labor costs have come down as a share of sales, while
restructuring activity abounds. Balance sheets are both smaller and less
leveraged. However, much work remains. For example, although profits are high
relative to GDP, the return on assets (RoA) for non-financial firms remains
below 3%, well below the 4% average prior to the 1990s. Although the profit
margin (profits/sales ratio) has risen significantly, turnover (sales/asset
ratio) remains mired near 1.0x, compared with 1.4x prior to 1990.
With both
the need and the ability to reallocate assets, a quickening of corporate
restructuring seems likely. There are some parts missing, however. First,
corporate revitalization requires realization of losses. Enhancement of both
carrots (such as better tax treatment of losses) and sticks (such stricter
oversight of bank loan classifications) will be important signposts. Second,
the partnership between business, banks, and the newly formed Industrial
Revitalization Corporation of Japan (IRCJ) needs to be strengthened.
Cyclical
Backdrop: Goldilocks Needed
For micro
and macro reforms to work, the cyclical position of the Japanese economy must
be strong enough to avoid paralysis, but weak enough to avoid complacency.
Fortunately, the business cycle is likely to tread precisely this “goldilocks
path.” Capex is likely to grow, but not strongly; consumption to be stable, but
not weak; and foreign demand to rise, but not surge. Although Japanese growth
on balance is likely to slow, it is not likely to collapse, and thus not likely
to endanger reform efforts.
Markets
in the Year of Truth
In this
environment, the equity market is likely to rise moderately in 2004, as my
colleague Naoki Kamiyama points out. However, due to reforms, there could be
further distinction between winners and losers. Nor are the currency markets
likely to be affected heavily by the reform agenda. Rather, as pointed out by
my colleague Stephen Jen, the theme in currency markets will be the fall of the
dollar, with a very modest further appreciation of the yen against it likely.
Risks
in the Outlook
Most of
the risks are negative. In the policy arena, the major risk is political. If
the opposition parties prove ineffective, then pressure on the LDP may subside,
and reform may slow. From the global economy, there are growth risks in both
the US and China. Also, continued high oil prices
could raise costs — although a stronger yen would cushion some of the pain. At
home, financial shocks could occur, as bad loan disposal proceeds.
Important Disclosure Information at the end of this Forum
Japan: ZIRP-Phobia
Takehiro Sato (Tokyo)
Is
the consensus correct?
While the
markets are discounting global tightening in 2004, we think investors should
question this consensus. Our US
economic team is forecasting that the Fed will move into a tightening phase from
July-September 2004, and recent steady improvement in economic data and the
FOMC’s return to a neutral stance in December support this view. At the same
time, however, US core CPI fell MoM in November for the first decline since December
1982 and recorded the lowest YoY result in 40 years since May 1963 despite a
sharp decline in the dollar’s value. Although the FOMC statement raises the
pricing outlook to equal risks of an unwelcome fall and a rise in inflation,
recent price developments run contrary to the Fed conclusion. The optimistic
interpretation is that it is not unusual for a supply shock from productivity
improvement to apply downward pressure on prices during the initial stage of
economic recovery. Yet we believe Japan’s
past two short-lived cyclical recoveries confirm the extreme vulnerability to
negative shocks of economies experiencing disinflation with high levels of
debt. We doubt whether the Fed has any basis to rush into tightening in the
current economic environment. (This assertion fully recognizes the risk of
going beyond our coverage, however.). Similarly, our European economic team
sees an increased likelihood of a move up of the tightening schedule by the ECB
in reaction to fiscal expansion policies being promoted by the German and
French governments that undermine the Stability Pact. Recent gains that have
taken the euro into new territory, however, raise questions about this outlook.
Our currency economist team envisions a sustained, large decline in the dollar
into 2005. If this aggressive forecast is accurate, tightening may not
necessarily be the next action.
Fed
impact on BoJ exit strategy
We expect the monetary policy stances of
US and European central banks to influence the BoJ’s exit strategy. Just as the
Fed has closely studied the BoJ’s failure and steered clear of unconventional
policies (thereby avoiding the morass of quantitative easing), the BoJ is
closely watching the Fed’s exit strategy. We think it is fairly evident that Japan is
likely to be the last major country to raise rates. Yet if the Fed launches a
tightening campaign, we expect increased speculation about a BoJ exit strategy
and a very different market environment in the second half of 2004. Advocates
of tighter monetary policy could unnerve bond market optimists. However,
speculation about an exit strategy may subside if foreign central banks show
less inclination to make rate adjustments amid the current disinflation trend.
Currency rates are also an issue. While recent yen strength is only having a
limited impact on corporate earnings, we anticipate a deflationary impact if
the rate takes hold at a level sharply below ¥100/US$1, as happened in 1995.
Even stronger reasons for our outlook of no significant change in Japan’s
monetary policy during 2004 are: 1) little chance of the core CPI rate
stabilizing in positive territory during 2004-05 (the explicit hurdle for an
exit strategy); and 2) the growing requirement for the BoJ to support the
financial system, since passage of the proposed new law allowing preemptive
public capital assistance is unlikely to restore financial health at regional
financial institutions, and the schedule for adopting payoff in April 2005 is
much too tight. We think the consensus view of adopting the payoff system as a
condition for dismantling ZIRP is unrealistic. There is actually a possibility
of the Bank conducting the symbolic easing by raising the current-account
target depending on currency market trends. Market fears are unlikely to
materialize in 2004, and we anticipate an ongoing policy gridlock.
ZIRP
worries persist with disinflation
While the policy rate slipping into the
1% range should effectively cripple monetary policy, judging from Japan’s
experience as the frontrunner in global deflation, the recent strong rebound by
the US economy is contradicting our cynical view. Decisive differences in
the performances of the two economies are deflation in Japan vs.
disinflation in the US and whether widespread asset price deflation exists. Yet we think
it is too early to rule out the zero-interest-rate threat. Even in Japan’s
case, it took just under four years for the policy rate to drop from the 1%
range in 1995 to zero. Following the exhaustion of the inventory cycle as in
the 1996 recovery from a boom in IT-related capex, and the negative cycle of
financial instability and credit contraction in 1997-98, the BoJ finally found
it necessary to implement ZIRP in early 1999. While the Bank considered a rate
hike in summer 1996, it backed off this stance as recovery momentum slumped. Japan’s
record highlights the vulnerability of economies with high levels of debt to
negative shocks, even in the case of disinflation rather than deflation. We
cannot say conclusively that the G-3 central banks no longer face the threat of
ZIRP.
Important Disclosure Information at the end of this Forum
Japan: Less Reliant on External Demand
Osamu Tanaka (Tokyo)
A hiccup to come, but then a renewed recovery
We are
expecting external demand and capex to drive a continuation of the moderate
recovery during the first half of 2004, but as deteriorated terms of trade hurt
corporate profits and exports slow down under a strong yen and cooling in the
China economy, we think the second half of 2004 will bring a downturn. Our view
is that this will be shallow and short-lived, however, as overseas economies
should keep rebounding and a severe inventory adjustment is likely to be
avoided, allowing the economy to resume its steady recovery in 2005. Our real
GDP growth forecasts are 2.0% in F2003, 1.7% in F2004, and 1.8% in F2005; for
calendar years, our projections are growth of 2.2% in 2003, 1.9% in 2004, and
1.5% in 2005.
Reasons
to expect the recovery to last in the near term include (1) continued growth in
exports as overseas economies keep rebounding, (2) an ongoing pick-up in
production and capital investment reflecting improved business confidence and
export expansion, (3) support for consumption from a gradual upturn in incomes.
However, concerns further out have not been cleared up, and the structural
problems that beset Japan’s industries make it very unlikely
that consumption or business investment will boom.
From the
second half of next year, meanwhile, we look for the economy to turn down
again. This is because (1) worsening in the terms of trade from a lull in the
restructuring effects amid deflation and higher prices for energy resources
will weigh on corporate earnings, (2) the export driver may lose momentum as
the effect of yen appreciation shows through after a time lag and China’s
economy slows, and (3) a drop in domestic and overseas demand would create
inventory adjustment pressures. Japan’s consumers have been running down
their savings for several years and will need to redress the balance, so
consumption is likely to stay level even if incomes edge higher, and as Japan moves down the path of fiscal
restraint, public spending will continue to cramp the economy. Housing
investment is another area where we do not expect sustained upside given the
uncertainties households confront, despite the extension of tax breaks.
That
said, we think a severe downturn will be avoided and see the period of slowdown
in the second half of 2004 as just a hiccup during the cyclical rebound. The
first reason is that export growth, although it decelerates, should continue.
The US economy should maintain a rapid pace of growth in 2004, with tax cuts
still boosting consumption and latent demand for investment breaking out after the
progress in scrapping excess capacity. The impact of tax concessions will fade
in 2005, resulting in slower growth that year, but this would simply be a
reaction to front-loading of demand in 2004, not a sign of a significant
retreat in the US economy. As for China, the impact of tighter monetary
policy is a concern, but even if domestic demand there cools, the effect on Japan’s exports should be comparatively
slight, since many of these are supplies of components for local assembly at
Japanese plants, whose final destination is outside China. The second reason is that
inventory adjustment pressure in the downturn should be limited, since the
rebound was tepid to begin with. Third, the long period of stagnation after the
bubble collapse should mean a considerable amount of pent-up and replacement
demand. Fourth, the provision of safety nets has created a system where crises
can be forestalled.
Structural problems likely to return to the
fore when cyclical recovery dies down
Although
various pressures from structural problems have been blunted by the ongoing
cyclical recovery, we expect the market to focus once more upon the obstacles that
structural problems pose to a true recovery, at the same time that the cyclical
recovery starts to lose steam in F2H04. A number of reform milestones are set
for around this time, so the government cannot afford to slack off on
structural reform. At the same time, the Diet elections in July 2004 and the
lifting of the payoff ban in April 2005 will make it difficult for the
administration to do anything that causes pain, such as job losses or corporate
bankruptcies. Thus, the government’s reform path will likely be one of
incremental inching-forward, so unfortunately we see little chance that Japan’s structural issues will be
resolved swiftly, or that the economy will trace a V-shaped recovery
trajectory. Of course, we look for the trend for private sector firms to nurse
themselves back to health to spread, and we are heartened that the foundations
are being laid for a sustained economic expansion further down the line.
Looking for balanced growth that is less
dependent on external demand
Morgan Stanley’s
global economic outlook now calls for global growth to accelerate to 4.2% in
2004, and then to drop off to 3.7% in 2005. The main culprits behind the
decline are expected to be the US and Asia, which are the chief importers from
Japan, and as the yen continues its rise, it is inevitable that doubt will be
cast upon the sustainability of an export-led recovery in Japan’s economy.
Certainly, exports have fueled the current recovery, but domestic demand is
starting to pick up steam and the tolerance for slowing external demand is
strengthening of late. Rising capex is the other cornerstone of the recovery,
as it may also reflects an increase in capex connected with export goods, so
some are of the opinion that the reliance on overseas demand will not change.
However, the October machinery order data pointed to a simultaneous strong
increase in domestic demand amid a slowdown in overseas demand, indicating that
the recovery is becoming broader-based. Industrial shipments also pointed to
improvement in domestic demand: Although in 2002, shipments for export
increased 9.5% YoY, domestic shipments declined 2.1% on average over January-September
2003, while export shipments rose 3.0% YoY, whereas domestic shipments
increased 2.9%. As the recovery shifts from being driven by external demand to
more balanced growth, we expect Japan to ride out downturns in the global
economy and the impact of a strong yen, and stay on a recovery track in 2005.
Important Disclosure Information at the end of this Forum
China: Bubbly Again
Andy Xie (Hong Kong)
Asian economies experienced a massive
swing in 2003. The looming war in Iraq cast a long shadow over the region at the beginning of the year and
threatened its trade-led recovery. Then the SARS epidemic engulfed the region
in the spring and activity practically came to a stop. Domestic demand began
to collapse in most of the region’s economies, even as exports held steady.
The SARS epidemic began to burn out in May, as the extreme caution taken by the
public and governments nipped the epidemic in the bud.
The shocks, however, only delayed the
powerful recovery in the global economy that was already under way. The
massive monetary and fiscal stimuli that governments around the world
instituted after the IT bubble burst and September 11 were working into the
global economy. The delay only made the recovery more powerful. By the middle
of the year, financial markets were waking up to a dramatic global recovery.
By the fall, the financial markets had
already priced in a vigorous global rebound. The third quarter turned out to
be the strongest for the global economy in decades, which validated the market
optimism. The dramatic strength in the third quarter was due to pent-up demand
that built in the pipeline as businesses and consumers postponed spending in
response to SARS and the war in Iraq.
China was the key
difference in this year’s global economy. Its imports are likely to increase
by US$120 billion in 2003, more than the increase in US imports at about US$100
billion. Over 80% of the increase in China’s imports was in raw materials and equipment. The surge in Chinese
demand for such products pushed up prices for most commodities. Nickel has led
the pack and appreciated by 80% this year. Copper, tin, and lead prices have
appreciated by over 40%. We have seen tremendous appreciation in the commodity
currencies.
The surge in China’s equipment imports was the most important factor in the revival of
Japan and Korea’s exports. Equipment exporting
economies in Europe also
benefited significantly from the surge in Chinese demand. It was probably the
most important factor in the earnings revival among equipment producers around
the world.
In addition to China’s demand for materials and equipment to power its production
machine, the US consumer has
remained a major engine for the global economy. Imports from China have accounted for 28% of the
increase in US imports this year, mineral fuel another 42%. Most Chinese
exports to the US are consumer
products distributed through well-known chain stores. A buoyant US consumer continues to drive its import
dynamics.
The potent cocktail of the US consumer and Chinese producer have been
powering the global economy. But their combined strength in the second half of
2003 was probably exaggerated by the pent-up demand from the first half.
Further, China is trying to
slow its economy to a sustainable pace as it faces up to resource constraints
and structural imbalances. There should be less fuel for the global economy next
year.
Nevertheless, the low base from the first
half of 2003 will likely deliver impressive year-on-year growth rates for most
Asian economies in the first half of 2004. Korea’s credit bubble burst this year, pushing some pent-up demand into
next year as well. This is why we expect next year’s growth rate to be
stronger than this year’s for most economies, with the exception of China.
Global financial markets, especially in Asia, are simply euphoric, in my view. We
are probably witnessing another equity mania. Foreign funds have flowed
rapidly into Asia, especially
from the US. Initial public
offerings are experiencing dotcom-like surges on their first day of trading.
Investors are buying because they expect others to do the same. The ‘greater
fool’ game is at play again.
Loose Fed policy is the cause of it all,
in my view. As the Fed is reviving the US economy without structural adjustment to cure the excesses, it has
to keep its monetary policy looser and for longer than usual. The spillover into
emerging markets is creating bubbles around the world, which may cause excesses
and lay the foundations for future problems. When the Fed has to reverse its
policy, we may see financial crises again.
Important Disclosure Information at the end of this Forum
Hong Kong: Balancing the Costs and Benefits of Greater China Integration
Denise Yam (Hong Kong)
Hong
Kong has seen a
massive swing in sentiment in 2003, from extreme pessimism amid the SARS
outbreak in 1H, to euphoric stock market gains in 2H. Beyond the cyclical recovery that should
persist well into 1H04, the medium-term roadmap for the Hong Kong economy
continues to be shaped by further economic integration with China, and how it
strikes a delicate balance between costs and benefits of such integration. Interestingly, over the past few years, the
market rallies, sometimes disproportionately, on the back of
“goodies” from integration in periods of positive sentiment, and
exaggerates concerns over the structural costs of integration when the mood is gloomy. Looking into 2004, events and trends should
further illustrate the opportunities and challenges associated with the
disappearing border and increasing mobility of labor and capital. We will try to identify the linkages among
all the economic issues and analyze developments under this framework.
Hong
Kong’s
economic roadmap is essentially the balance between positives and negatives of
its integration with China under the circumstances of a fixed
exchange rate. Its “wish
list,” which rests with the central Beijing government, encompasses measures that
secure and progressively extend Hong Kong’s first-mover advantage in the promising
Chinese market. The opportunity to
front-run other WTO members in market access, derived from its preferential
relationship with China, was formally endorsed in the Closer
Economic Partnership Arrangement launched mid-year. The deliberate naming of CEPA as an
“Arrangement” rather than an “Agreement” signals
Beijing’s ongoing support for Hong Kong, and implicitly promises the
gradual realization of other items on the wish list. Aside from the relaxation in
Mainlanders’ tourist visits to Hong Kong that has brought about a quick
fix to the SARS-battered economy since mid-2003, the first step toward
introducing Renminbi financial services in Hong Kong represents the most
promising development in enhancing its status as an international financial
center, and paves the way for immense opportunities as China progressively
relaxes its restrictions on cross-border financial transactions.
Hong
Kong’s
structural pests, namely deflation, unemployment, and fiscal deficit, are not
new to anyone. While many still insist
that they have resulted from the 1997 crisis and should ease upon a cyclical
recovery, we are convinced that their persistence has a close association with
Greater China integration, but that they only presented themselves as the 1997
crisis triggered the collapse of the asset bubble. The CPI has fallen 16% from the peak in 1998,
and the GDP deflator 23%, but the narrowing of the price gap could only
continue amid increasing flows of labor and capital across the disappearing
border. Hong Kong university graduates are now competing
with their Mainland counterparts for jobs in the Pearl River Delta. The fiscal deficit has resulted in the
erosion of the revenue base by deflation and the northward shift in consumption
and productive economic activity, and the downward inflexibility of the public
sector’s cost base. Although the
cyclical recovery appears looks promising to ease deflation and unemployment,
we should not underestimate the pressure from millions waiting to be employed
and hectares of land waiting to be developed, which is set to linger for many
years to come.
Looking into
2004, real economic growth for Hong Kong amid the realization of Chinese “goodies”
could well surprise on the upside, exacerbated by the low base effect from
SARS. The unemployment rate is easing as
opportunities in the Mainland help absorb job seekers. We currently forecast real GDP growth of 4.5%
for 2004, and a 1.5-2 percentage point ease in the jobless rate. The fiscal deficit could narrow by HK$25 bn
(2% of GDP) in FY2005 amid the cyclical upturn as the government collects more
taxes from the improved economy, but will still be far from being eliminated
until we see radical fiscal reform measures.
Nevertheless, we still stand out from the crowd in reiterating that any
surprise to inflation will likely be on the downside (current forecast is -1%
for 2004), as it is simply too naïve to ignore the deflationary pressure from
Hong Kong merging into an economy with 186 times its population but only 5% of
its per capita income.
Hong
Kong places
immense trust in the leaders in Beijing in their support for the economy,
independent of any displeasure with the local government. We share the optimism that there are enormous
opportunities that China could offer to sustain Hong Kong’s economic growth. Nevertheless, effective implementation is
vital in maximizing the benefits from these valuable opportunities, against the
structural costs of integration.
Eventual success in reviving the economy still depends on coordinated
measures on the domestic front.
Otherwise, valuable opportunities could well be wasted rather than
constructively and profitably leveraged.
Important Disclosure Information at the end of this Forum
India: Ready for Takeoff?
Chetan Ahya (Mumbai)
Successful Transition from Isolation to
Integration
The economic reforms that began in F1992 (YE March)
have successfully enabled the Indian economy to transition from a shackled
environment to a deregulated, globally integrated market. Average GDP
growth in F1993-F2003 accelerated to 6% (per capita growth of 4%) compared with
5.8% (per capita growth of 3.1%) in the 1980s. Continued healthy growth
in the past 10 years has helped expand the Indian economy to US$512 billion in
F2003 from US$258 billion in F1993.
Rising Up the Curve of Emerging Market
Lifecycle
While economic reforms implemented in the past 10
years have not meaningfully helped accelerate GDP growth, the big difference
has been the improved macro stability imparted by an increasingly
market-oriented structure supported by an institutional framework. While
inherently unstable government pump priming supported growth in the 1980s,
during the 1990s growth was driven by inducing private sector investment,
deregulating industrial activities, and liberalization of foreign trade and
capital flows. These reforms have positioned India on
the rising path of the emerging market lifecycle. The key question now is
not the sustainability of current growth, but whether India can
manage to accelerate growth to 8% in the next three years.
So Far India Is Following a Different Growth Model
Annually, India
adds about 167,000 engineers and 2.2 million English-speaking graduates (with 15
years of basic education), giving the country a distinct advantage to
participate in the fast-evolving global trend of skilled labour
arbitrage. While most other Asian countries have taken advantage of
globalization in manufacturing, India has
relied on the high value-added services sector to accelerate growth. India is
becoming the services workshop to the world. We believe that Indian IT services
and ITES (IT enabled services) have the potential to earn annual export revenue
of US$33.8 billion (4.2% of GDP) by F2008, up from US$9.5 billion in
F2003. We estimate the contribution of these exports to GDP growth to
rise to 0.6% point by F2008 from 0.25% point in F2003.
But a Niche in Services May Not Be Enough
While we see great potential for India to
be the destination for outsourcing services, this won't be sufficient to
accelerate overall economic growth to 8%, in our view. We believe that to
sustain growth of 8%, manufacturing growth must also take place. An
increase in investment in this sector would also be necessary to create
employment for the fast-growing, semi-skilled, non-English-speaking
workforce. According to official figures, of the 400 million-strong
workforce in India, about 30 million are unemployed. However, we believe that
the disguised unemployment levels are significantly higher. Hence,
simultaneous progress in manufacturing will also be necessary for balanced
development that ensures the participation of lower-income earners in economic
progress and social stability.
Can Manufacturing Growth Revive?
After the reforms initiated in 1992, manufacturing
growth accelerated from -1% in F1992 to 12.3% in F1996. However, since
then it has tended to be in the range of 3-8%. Average manufacturing growth
over the last five years was 5.1%. Overall employment in the organized sector
has declined by 1% per annum (pa) in the five years ended F2002 compared to
growth of 1% pa in F1993-96. We believe that to accelerate manufacturing
growth on a sustained basis to 10% and above will be a challenging task
considering the current investment trend. India's
aggregate investments slowed to 22.4% of GDP in F2002 from 26.9% in F1996 due to
the lack of a supportive environment for investment.
The environment for investment in the manufacturing
sector appears constrained by factors such as risk of possible significant
reduction in tariff protection (which is currently at an average of 33%),
unfavourable labour laws, a cumbersome administrative framework, and the inability
to develop quality infrastructure facilities at a reasonable cost.
Recently, the government took several steps to improve infrastructure, but
progress remains slow. The government's consolidated fiscal deficit at
11% of GDP is also constraining it from spending aggressively on
infrastructure. While improving infrastructure across the board is likely to be
difficult, we believe that in the short term the government should aim to
create special economic zones (SEZs) near coastal areas with state-of-the-art
infrastructure and minimal administrative interference. Unfortunately,
the government has made no major effort to set up SEZs with world-class
infrastructure.
Low Savings Rate Could be an Additional
Constraint
Even if the government improves the environment for
manufacturing, capital accumulation could be restrained by low domestic
savings. India's saving rate is still lower than that in most other Asian
economies. One of the key reasons for the high growth in Asia ex Japan
(excluding India) has been saving rates of around 35% of GDP. However, in India
saving rates are 24% of GDP, and the FDI inflow is less than 1% of GDP,
restricting capital formation at about 25% of GDP. Given India's
average incremental capital output ratio (ICOR) of about 4%, it would be
difficult to see sustained GDP growth of above 6-6.5%. We believe that in
the near term a policy change targeting an increase in public saving and higher
foreign direct investment could help augment investment rates and consequently
growth rates.
The bottom line: We believe that India
will see acceleration in its average GDP growth to 6-6.5% pa over the next
three years compared with the average rate of 5.5% over the last five
years. However, for growth to take off to 8% or above would require a
significant improvement in the policy environment, especially for the
development of infrastructure and to increase investment in the economy.
Although this goal is possible, the government's efforts at implementation have
been less than aggressive so far.
Important Disclosure Information at the end of this Forum
Asia Pacific: Parties, Solutions, Second Track and Social Capitalism
Daniel Lian (Singapore)
Cyclical Parties
The global economy is increasingly
afflicted by ‘party syndrome’. Central banks around the world frequently
resort to easy monetary policy to solve cyclical woes. The present
liquidity-driven ‘party’ and economic recovery is a case in point. It is
perhaps working as the global economy is responding to positive doses of
monetary drugs; however, this cannot constitute a structural solution. In our
view, the world economy is confronted with significant structural impediments
that over time cannot be resolved by such simple monetary tools.
The ‘Number One’ Macro-Structural
Impediment
In my view, the world is experiencing the
greatest welfare transfer ever seen across geographical regions and across
generations. Such ‘transfers’ are embodied in an economic dynamic that has
been characterized by a process in which Asia’s gigantic export machine has
ensured that trade and current account surpluses have been finely balanced
against the global imbalance in savings. For the last several decades, Asia has aggressively exported to the US and the world, but passively
accumulated savings chiefly in US Treasuries and other foreign assets. This
facilitates the US and some
parts of the developed world’s enjoyment of excessively stronger currencies and
lower domestic interest rates, which in turn have fuelled these countries’
private consumption.
In a nutshell, Asia’s obsession with exports and savings has enabled present
generations of the US and some
parts of the developed world to sustain an unusually high present rate of
consumption, at the expense of present generations in Asia. This is because Asian exchange rates are artificially low and
exports are artificially cheap, and Asia has suppressed its present consumption to subsidize buyers of its
exports. It also comes at the expense of future generations of the American
economy and some parts of the developed world. At some point, present
consumption in these countries would have to give way to saving to restore
macro imbalances, and future generations would have to bear the economic burden
of an aging population, as well as the devaluation of their currencies and
retirement of their public and private debt.
The twin global imbalances of trade and
savings have exacerbated the third global imbalance — pricing power disparity.
The biggest misfortune of Asia
is the negative effect on output prices caused by Asian firms’ obsession for
export volume and their ‘price-taking’ (i.e., no pricing power) approach to
outsourcing work for multinationals and, as a consequence, depressed input
prices for Asian labor and low returns on Asian capital. Asia/Pacific
countries are primarily in the business of supplying manufactured goods,
agricultural products and natural resources to the rest of the world.
International prices for these goods directly affect returns for Asian
companies and the wages of Asian laborers. On the supply side, surplus
capacity means that reduced prices do not discourage Asian manufacturers and
producers from supplying the global market. On the demand side, any abrupt
change in demand results in violent price swings rather than on quantity
produced as companies typically sell more in a rising price environment and
sell even more in a declining price environment. The bottom line is that
Asia/Pacific’s terms of trade worsen every time global demand for electronics,
agricultural products or primary commodities goes into a downswing.
Probable Structural Solutions
There are three probable structural
solutions to overcome the number one structural impediment:
(1) Revaluation of Asian currencies
against the US dollar and currencies of the parts of the developed world that
also experienced such imbalances;
(2) An ‘institutionalized’ rise in Asian
wages relative to the US and
the developed world;
(3) Structurally boosting domestic demand
in Asia.
While solutions (1) and (2) are being
perceived by some quarters of the policy-making and economist professions as
the right structural answers, they are rather impractical solutions because of
two difficulties. First, they are hard to implement, and second, they are
rather blunt macro instruments as they are likely to exert an indiscriminate
impact on the Asian economies, causing misallocation of resources and
micro-macro pains. However, I believe the third proposition has more merit and
deserves careful consideration.
Overcoming the Most Pressing
Impediment
There are two misconceptions about a
structural rise in domestic demand in Asian economies. First, many regard Asia as incapable of generating a
structural rise in domestic demand because of its dependence on exports.
Second, many consider a structural rise in domestic demand as being tantamount
to a mere cyclical spurt in private consumption or an unsustained rise in
government spending. Both views are false, in my view. I believe Asia can indeed shed its excessive
dependence on exports and create structural resilience in domestic demand.
Southeast Asia as
a region, in my view, particularly needs to address the ‘number one’ structural
impediment elaborated upon above because the impediment perpetuates Asia’s dependence on external demand and
FDI by MNCs. However, compared with other parts of Asia, Southeast Asia can
ill afford to perpetuate such dependency. Southeast
Asia’s economic living space is increasingly squeezed
by the reconstructing of multinationals’ global supply chains, as such
reconstruction decisively favors China and India. China is sailing through the successful
EAEM (East Asia Economic Model) — the single track development path that
leverages FDI by MNCs and mass manufacturing for export — that is no longer
very relevant to Southeast Asia.
The rise of India as the number
one choice for services outsourcing for multinationals is also likely to be at
the expense of Southeast Asia
both in terms of FDI inflow, MNC jobs and services revival.
As China and India are able
to expand their living space, Hong Kong and Taiwan are
integrated into the Greater China economic sphere, and Japan and Korea leverage
their technology and global market share, the ‘skin-deep’ industrialization of Southeast Asia will be put to the test.
Consequently, we believe Southeast Asia must engineer a successful structural lift in domestic demand in
order to shed its excessive dependence on exports. In the process, the region
must work towards restoring its share of global imbalances. This can be
achieved through the implementation of the dual track strategy as its dominant
economics strategy and the rise of social capitalism as the dominant
social-political-economic complex.
Dual Track Economic Strategy Shifts
Mr. Thaksin’s dual track development
strategy implemented in Thailand over the past three years, in my view offers the first concrete
case of a successful structural lift in domestic demand of a Southeast Asian
economy. One must first understand that the dual track strategy means erecting
a second track of growth engine working side by side with the traditional first
engine of growth — the mass manufacturing based export engine.
The second track has two dimensions. The
first dimension concerns policy initiatives aimed at producing a structural
lift in domestic demand. This would alter the mix of external and domestic
demand in terms of contribution to growth as well as overall output. In the
context of Thailand, it takes
the form of efforts to shed excessive ‘single track’ dependence on mass
manufacturing for export: we call this the ‘domestic demand element’ of the
second track. The second dimension concerns creation of a ‘local enterprise
element’ of the second track consisting of local enterprise and product
development alternatives to mass manufacturing for export. Local enterprises
would not only produce for local demand, but also their indigenously created
and developed products would help to open new export markets by leveraging the
country’s indigenous and unique skills and resources.
Thailand’s ability to generate good
growth through its newfound vigor in domestic demand while retaining export
competitiveness over the past three years owes a great deal of credit to the
dual track strategy, in our view. It demonstrates that a structural lift in
domestic demand can happen in Southeast Asia and that this does not necessarily come at the price of destruction
of export capability, or through revaluation of currency or an indiscriminate
rise in wages.
Social Capitalism a Larger New Complex
I believe a new development thesis as
well as a new social-economic-political complex for the Developing World is emerging — ‘social capitalism’. The rise of such
a new thesis can be traced to the failure of the capitalist development model —
the development apparatus adopted by most developing countries — to create
sustained and even growth for the Developing World over the past several
decades. We shall first examine the background and causes of the perceived failure
of the capitalist development model, and defer the formal definition of social
capitalism to the end of this article.
Before we analyze why the capitalist
development model appears to have failed in the developing world, one must
first appreciate the big picture of economic development history. Such a
history is dominated principally by the crash of the developed
world — the capitalist, free enterprise market model and the central planning
communist-socialist model.
In a nutshell, while capitalism has
triumphed over communism after the fall of the Berlin Wall and almost a century
of ‘political-economic’ struggle, the Keynesian model of a ‘mixed economy’ has
hardly any relevance for the developing world economies. The Keynesian mixed
economy is primarily a domestic economic policy model adhered to by Western
democracies. It is designed for the Developed World masses who had found a way
to ‘appropriate’ economic profits and rents from the capitalists and other
privileged classes of their societies. As the Developed World is prosperous — it
possesses the majority of the economic wealth of the world — its governments are
able to operate a ‘socialist’ redistributive apparatus to balance the excessive
‘profit’ quest of their corporate-capitalists, and the ‘social welfare’ needs
of the not-so-well-off in their societies.
The economic development model adhered to
by the Developing World, however, remains decisively ‘capitalist’ in nature:
there is no Keynesian redistributive channel whereby the Developed World is ‘obliged’
to share its excessive profits and wealth with the developing world. This is
despite the fact that the Developed World’s profit and wealth accumulation has a
great deal to do with its Developing World production sites and its access to Developing
World markets, savings and resources. Indeed, the aid and low-cost loans made
available to the Developing World appear puny compared with the Developed World’s ‘windfalls’ derived from its
investment and trade with the Developing World.
In consequence, the Developing World has
been an unhappy lot. From the end of the Second World War to the present, out
of a hundred or more Developing World nations that have emerged, few have truly
attained ‘developed’ status. South Korea and Taiwan, and the
atypical Singapore, which owes
much of its prosperity to its ‘middleman’ roles in Southeast
Asia, are the few exceptions. Yes, there is GDP
growth and a concomitant rise in nominal income in the Developing World, but
the vast majority of its residents remain in relative poverty.
Three Shortcomings in a Capitalist
Development Model
The capitalist development model is the
mode of interaction between the Developed World economies and the Developing
World economies. Such economic interaction is conducted primarily via two
channels — investment and trade. Both channels are intertwined and are driven
by the ‘quest for profit’ by the corporate-capitalist class of the Developed
World, represented chiefly through MNCs. Investment by the Developed World is
carried out largely in the following three major forms of investment activity: (1)
the outsourcing of mass manufacturing activities taking advantage of cheap
labor or investment incentives; (2) the exploitation of resources (primary
commodities and agriculture) used either as productive input or for consumption
by the Developed World; and (3) the penetration of Developing World domestic
markets either in goods or services (see our report First Step in
Dismantling the East Asia Economic Model, May 16, 2001).
Proponents of such a capitalist development
model argue that it is the only way the Developed World can help the Developing
World to attain economic growth and prosperity. This is too vast a subject for
the scope of this paper. However, such a capitalist development model has three major shortcomings, in our view.
First, the Developing World is
deprived of indigenously owned capital
This is because the initial capital for
industrialization and the production capacity that is subsequently developed
are supplied and controlled by Western capitalists. The outsourcing of MNC
production in the Developing World is contingent on the ‘obedience’ of
political regimes as well as favorable investment incentives catered for by
such regimes. Tax, labor, local market penetration and export promotion are
key features of such incentives. We see other significant disadvantages
associated with such an ‘FDI by MNC’ development model: production capacity
concentrates on either mass manufacturing that forms part of the global supply
chains controlled by Western companies, or on the exploitation of Developing
World resources (such as primary commodities and agriculture).
Second, the Developing World does
not enjoy pricing power for its output and exports
As production capacity, production
decisions, volumes and terms of trade are dictated by Developed World
corporate-capitalists and their distribution chains, Developing World products
and exports have not developed genuine pricing power, despite being a critical
part of global production chains. Under-investment in ‘intellectual capital’ has
compounded the problem.
Third, the Developing World
experiences an uneven and inequitable development path under the capitalistic
route
As the capitalist development strategy is
to build factories and to move surplus labor from rural and agricultural
sectors to production capacity based in the cities, income and wealth
inequality have typically worsened. Indeed, over-development of industry and
urban sectors often comes at the expense of the development potential of the rural,
agricultural, resource and SME sectors.
Social Capitalism Attempts to Address
Capital and Pricing Power Impediments
‘Social capitalism’, or the
social-capitalist development model, thus aims to address these shortcomings by
creating indigenously owned productive capital and attaining pricing power for
the Developing World.
Much of the foundation of social capitalism
is laid down by Hernando De Soto, a Peruvian development economist, alongside a
score of other development economists who have paid close attention to the
development obstacles confronted by Developing World economies. Their main
thesis suggests that substantial ‘dead capital’ resides largely in rural and
informal sectors; policy makers, by devising ‘capital creation’ mechanisms can convert
this dead capital into ‘legal’ and Western-style capital for development needs.
The other critical dimension of social capitalism
lies in balancing past excesses — such as excessive dependence on external
demand, mass manufacturing and other FDI by MNC-driven economic activities —
with a strengthened development platform via programs to structurally lift
domestic demand and develop domestic enterprises. We think this is
particularly relevant for ex-China, smaller developing economies in Southeast Asia
that are suffering both a deterioration in pricing power and a shrinking role
in the global mass manufacturing supply chain.
It is important to note that the rise of
social capitalism entails a new social-economic-political complex encompassing
the second track economic phenomenon. Social capitalism is not a wholesale
rejection of capitalism or the existing capitalistic development model. It would
be entirely impractical for the Developing World to reject free trade or FDI,
or to circumvent a Western capital- and technology-led development path. In
our view, integration with the Western economy must remain the ‘core’
development thrust of social capitalism.
Mr. Thaksin’s Experiment with the Dual
Track and Social-Capitalist Development Model
Over the past three years, Thailand under
the leadership of Prime Minister Thaksin Shinawatra, has been the only country in
Asia to initiate a full-scale experiment of social capitalism — i.e., through the
dual track development model (see my report Twin Dimensions of Mr. Thaksin’s
Dual Track Model, May 7, 2003). In our view, Mr. Thaksin’s dual track
development model is the closest approximation to practical social capitalism: it
is structurally reducing Thailand’s dependence on MNCs and
strengthened domestic demand, and at the same time is
‘creating’ capital and ‘improving’ pricing power.
Mr. Thaksin’s first track continues to
encourage FDI — but only quality FDI that makes sense to the Thai economy — and
pushes for export growth and globalization. The continued integration with the
West and the world should ensure that the Thai economy remains competitive and
relevant. The SMEs and services sectors promoted under the second track are
pro export as well.
Other than the twin dimension of the
second track that we elaborated upon above, it is important to appreciate that
integral parts of the dual track strategy are initiatives to ‘create’ capital
to facilitate the ‘development’ of local enterprises with niche pricing power.
Over the past three years, various ‘capital creation’ projects are being
conceived and put in place, aimed at converting ‘dead’ capital into productive
capital or at enabling the capital-deficient sectors to form capital. Such
capital-deficient sectors include urban poor, rural, resource, SME and the
government sectors. In a short span of 32 months, numerous ‘capital’ projects have
been either aggressively implemented or creatively conceived. These include
the Village Fund project launched in 2001, the Capital Creation scheme
conceived in 2002 (see my report Capital Creation — The Next Step Up,
January 16, 2003), housing projects for state workers and for the masses (see This
Siam House Is Different, May 16, 2003), various SME initiatives introduced
since 2001, the state enterprise privatization program, and the latest Vayupak
Mutual Fund initiative (see Vayupak, November 7, 2003.)
Bottom Line: Second Track and Social
Capitalism could Be Southeast Asia’s Answer to Global Imbalance and Shrinking Living Space
The recent global recovery is just
another party created by monetary excesses of global central banks. Asia’s
excess saving and obsession with exports have enabled present generations of
the US and some parts of the developed world to enjoy welfare transfers from
present generations in Asia and future generations of the US and the developed
world. There are three probable solutions to overcome this perpetual global
imbalance: (1) revaluation of Asian currencies against the US dollar and
currencies of the parts of the developed world that also experienced such
imbalances; (2) an ‘institutionalized’ rise in Asian wages relative to the US and the developed world; and (3)
structurally boosting domestic demand in Asia.
Southeast Asia as
a region, in my view, particularly needs to address the ‘number one’ structural
impediment elaborated upon above because the impediment perpetuates Asia’s dependence on external demand and
FDI by MNCs. However, compared with other parts of Asia, Southeast Asia can
ill afford to perpetuate such dependency. Southeast
Asia’s economic living space is increasingly squeezed
by the reconstructing of multinationals’ global supply chains as such
reconstruction decisively favors China and India. China is sailing through the successful
EAEM (East Asia Economic Model) — the single track development path that
leverages FDI by MNCs and mass manufacturing for export — that is no longer the
forte of Southeast Asia. The
rise of India as the number one
choice for services outsourcing for multinationals is also likely to be at the
expense of Southeast Asia both
in terms of FDI inflow, MNC jobs and services revival.
In consequence, we believe Southeast Asia must engineer a successful
structural lift in domestic demand in order to shed its excessive dependence on
exports. In the process, it must work towards restoring global imbalances
through implementation of the dual track strategy as its dominant economics
strategy and the rise of social capitalism as the dominant
social-political-economic complex. Thailand’s ability to generate good growth
through its new-found vigor in domestic demand while retaining export
competitiveness over the past three years gives a great deal of credit to the
dual track strategy, in our view. It demonstrates that a structural lift in
domestic demand can happen in Asia and that it does not necessarily come at the price of the complete
destruction of export capability, or through revaluation of currency or an
indiscriminate rise in wages.
The rise of social capitalism entails a
new social-economic-political complex encompassing the second track economic
phenomenon. This is not a wholesale rejection of capitalism or the existing
capitalist development model. Social capitalism’s main objective is to correct
the inadequate and imbalanced development path by reviving ‘dead capital’ and
to balance past excesses — excessive dependence on external demand, mass
manufacturing and other FDI by MNC-driven economic activities, and
industrialization at the expense of proper development in rural, agricultural,
resource and SME sectors. It aims to do this with a strengthened development
platform via programs to lift domestic demand structurally and to develop
domestic enterprises.
Social capitalism is a bigger phenomenon
than the second track strategy shifts because as well as encompassing economic
changes promoted by the second track, it is promoting wide and sweeping change
in the social-economic-political complex. For example, the rural sector is no
longer perceived as a development burden but rather as a new source of economic
strength. Concomitantly, there is a rise in the rural economy and rural
political power, as well as the elimination of the informal economy through the
creation of capital among the capital-deficient sectors. There is also the
creation of a new mass capitalist class that is drawn from SME and rural
enterprises that leverage on indigenous skills and resources at the expense of
the ‘rent-seeking’ crony capitalists.
Important Disclosure Information at the end of this Forum
Disclosure Statement
Morgan Stanley does and seeks to do business with companies covered in its research
reports. Investors should consider this report as only a single factor in making
their investment decision.
Important US
Regulatory Disclosures on Subject Companies
The information and opinions in this report were prepared by Morgan Stanley
& Co. Incorporated and its affiliates (collectively, "Morgan Stanley").
The research analysts, strategists, or research associates principally responsible
for the preparation of this research report have received compensation based
upon various factors, including quality of research, investor client feedback,
stock picking, competitive factors, firm revenues and overall investment banking
revenues.
ANALYST STOCK RATINGS
Overweight (O). The stock's total return is expected to exceed the average total
return of the analyst's industry (or industry team's) coverage universe, or
the relevant country MSCI index, on a risk-adjusted basis over the next 12-18
months. Equal-weight (E). The stock's total return is expected to be in line
with the average total return of the analyst's industry (or industry team's)
coverage universe, or the relevant country MSCI index, on a risk-adjusted basis
over the next 12-18 months. Underweight (U). The stock's total return is expected
to be below the average total return of the analyst's industry (or industry
team's) coverage universe, or the relevant country MSCI index, on a risk-adjusted
basis over the next 12-18 months. More volatile (V). We estimate that this stock
has more than a 25% chance of a price move (up or down) of more than 25% in
a month, based on a quantitative assessment of historical data, or in the analyst's
view, it is likely to become materially more volatile over the next 1-12 months
compared with the past three years. Stocks with less than one year of trading
history are automatically rated as more volatile (unless otherwise noted). We
note that securities that we do not currently consider "more volatile"
can still perform in that manner.
Ratings prior to March 18, 2002: SB=Strong Buy; OP=Outperform; N=Neutral; UP=Underperform.
For definitions, please go to www.morganstanley.com/companycharts.
ANALYST INDUSTRY VIEWS
Attractive (A). The analyst expects the performance of his or her industry coverage
universe to be attractive vs. the relevant broad market benchmark over the next
12-18 months. In-Line (I). The analyst expects the performance of his or her
industry coverage universe to be in line with the relevant broad market benchmark
over the next 12-18 months. Cautious (C). The analyst views the performance
of his or her industry coverage universe with caution vs. the relevant broad
market benchmark over the next 12-18 months.
Stock price charts and rating histories for companies discussed in this report
are also available at www.morganstanley.com/companycharts. You may also request
this information by writing to Morgan Stanley at 1585 Broadway, 14th Floor (Attention:
Research Disclosures), New York, NY, 10036 USA.
Other Important Disclosures
For a discussion, if applicable, of the valuation methods used to determine
the price targets included in this summary and the risks related to achieving
these targets, please refer to the latest relevant published research on these
stocks. Research is available through your sales representative or on Client
Link at www.morganstanley.com and other electronic systems.
This report does not provide individually tailored investment advice. It has
been prepared without regard to the individual financial circumstances and objectives
of persons who receive it. The securities discussed in this report may not be
suitable for all investors. Morgan Stanley recommends that investors independently
evaluate particular investments and strategies, and encourages investors to
seek the advice of a financial adviser. The appropriateness of a particular
investment or strategy will depend on an investor's individual circumstances
and objectives.
This report is not an offer to buy or sell any security or to participate in
any trading strategy. In addition to any holdings that may be disclosed above,
Morgan Stanley and/or its employees not involved in the preparation of this
report may have investments in securities or derivatives of securities of companies
mentioned in this report, and may trade them in ways different from those discussed
in this report. Derivatives may be issued by Morgan Stanley or associated persons.
Morgan Stanley is involved in many businesses that may relate to companies
mentioned in this report. These businesses include specialized trading, risk
arbitrage and other proprietary trading, fund management, investment services
and investment banking.
Morgan Stanley makes every effort to use reliable, comprehensive information,
but we make no representation that it is accurate or complete. We have no obligation
to tell you when opinions or information in this report change apart from when
we intend to discontinue research coverage of a subject company.
Reports prepared by Morgan Stanley research personnel are based on public information.
Facts and views presented in this report have not been reviewed by, and may
not reflect information known to, professionals in other Morgan Stanley business
areas, including investment banking personnel.
The value of and income from your investments may vary because of changes in
interest rates or foreign exchange rates, securities prices or market indexes,
operational or financial conditions of companies or other factors. There may
be time limitations on the exercise of options or other rights in your securities
transactions. Past performance is not necessarily a guide to future performance.
Estimates of future performance are based on assumptions that may not be realized.
This publication is disseminated in Japan by Morgan Stanley Japan Limited;
in Hong Kong by Morgan Stanley Dean Witter Asia Limited; in Singapore by Morgan
Stanley Dean Witter Asia (Singapore) Pte., regulated by the Monetary Authority
of Singapore; in Australia by Morgan Stanley Dean Witter Australia Limited A.B.N.
67 003 734 576, a licensed dealer, which accepts responsibility for its contents;
in certain provinces of Canada by Morgan Stanley Canada Limited, which has approved
of, and has agreed to take responsibility for, the contents of this publication
in Canada; in Spain by Morgan Stanley, S.V., S.A., a Morgan Stanley group company,
which is supervised by the Spanish Securities Markets Commission (CNMV) and
states that this document has been written and distributed in accordance with
the rules of conduct applicable to financial research as established under Spanish
regulations; in the United States by Morgan Stanley & Co. Incorporated and
Morgan Stanley DW Inc., which accept responsibility for its contents; and in
the United Kingdom, this publication is approved by Morgan Stanley & Co.
International Limited, solely for the purposes of section 21 of the Financial
Services and Markets Act 2000 and is distributed in the European Union by Morgan
Stanley & Co. International Limited, except as provided above.Private U.K.
investors should obtain the advice of their Morgan Stanley & Co. International
Limited representative about the investments concerned. In Australia, this report,
and any access to it, is intended only for "wholesale clients" within
the meaning of the Australian Corporations Act.
The trademarks and service marks contained herein are the property of their
respective owners. Third-party data providers make no warranties or representations
of any kind relating to the accuracy, completeness, or timeliness of the data
they provide and shall not have liability for any damages of any kind relating
to such data. The Global Industry Classification Standard ("GICS")
was developed by and is the exclusive property of MSCI and S&P.
This report or any portion hereof may not be reprinted, sold or redistributed
without the written consent of Morgan Stanley.
Additional information on recommended securities is available on request.
|
|
Steve Roach Weekly Commentary
The password for this webcast is "roach".
You can view this webcast using Windows Media Player, RealPlayer, or your telephone.
Other GEF links
The Global Economics Team
Archive
Japan Economic Forum
|
|